There’s a “convergence” theory in economics that suggests, over time, that “poor nations should catch up with rich nations.”
But in the real world, that seems to be the exception rather than the rule.
There’s an interesting and informative article at the St. Louis Federal Reserve Bank which explores this question. It asks why most low-income and middle-income nations are not “converging” with countries from the developed world.
…only a few countries have been able to catch up with the high per capita income levels of the developed world and stay there. By American living standards (as representative of the developed world), most developing countries since 1960 have remained or been “trapped” at a constant low-income level relative to the U.S. This “low- or middle-income trap” phenomenon raises concern about the validity of the neoclassical growth theory, which predicts global economic convergence. Specifically, the Solow growth model suggests that income levels in poor economies will grow relatively faster than developed nations and eventually converge or catch up to these economies through capital accumulation… But, with just a few exceptions, that is not happening.
Here’s a chart showing examples of nations that are – and aren’t – converging with the United States.
The authors analyze this data.
The figure above shows the rapid and persistent relative income growth (convergence) seen in Hong Kong, Singapore, Taiwan and Ireland beginning in the late 1960s all through the early 2000s to catch up or converge to the higher level of per capita income in the U.S. …In sharp contrast, per capita income relative to the U.S. remained constant and stagnant at 10 percent to 30 percent of U.S. income in the group of Latin American countries, which remained stuck in the middle-income trap and showed no sign of convergence to higher income levels… The lack of convergence is even more striking among low-income countries. Countries such as Bangladesh, El Salvador, Mozambique and Niger are stuck in a poverty trap, where their relative per capita income is constant and stagnant at or below 5 percent of the U.S. level.
The article concludes by asking why some nations converge and others don’t.
Why do some countries remain stagnant in relative income levels while some others are able to continue growing faster than the frontier nations to achieve convergence? Is it caused by institutions, geographic locations or smart industrial policies?
I’ll offer my answer to this question, though it doesn’t require any special insight.
Simply stated, Solow’s Growth Theory is correct, but needs to be augmented. Yes, nations should converge, but that won’t happen unless they have similar economic policies.
And if relatively poor nations want to converge in the right direction, that means they should liberalize their economies by shrinking government and reducing intervention.
Take a second look at the above chart above and ask whether there’s a commonality for the jurisdictions that are converging with the United States?
Why have Hong Kong, Singapore, Taiwan, and Ireland converged, while nations such as Mexico and Brazil remained flat?
The obvious answer is that the former group of jurisdictions have pursued, at least to some extent, pro-market policies.
Heck, they all rank among the world’s top-18 nations for economic freedom.
Hong Kong and Singapore have been role models for economic liberty for several decades, so it’s no surprise that their living standards have enjoyed the most impressive increase.
But if you dig into the data, you’ll also see that Taiwan’s jump began when it boosted economic freedom beginning in the late 1970s. And Ireland’s golden years began when it increased economic freedom beginning in the late 1980s.
The moral of the story is – or at least should be – very clear. Free markets and small government are the route to convergence.
Here’s a video tutorial.
And if you want some real-world examples of how nations with good policy “de-converge” from nations with bad policy, here’s a partial list.
* Chile vs. Argentina vs. Venezuela
* United States vs. Hong Kong and Singapore
* Botswana vs. other African nations
Gee, it’s almost enough to make you think there’s a relationship between good long-run growth and economic freedom!
[…] Kong didn’t just converge with one of the world’s richest countries, which by itself would be a remarkable and unusual achievement. It actually became […]
[…] think the answer to these questions is obvious, for what it’s […]
[…] bottom line is that Eastern European nations need to engage in a lot more reform (especially self-funding for things like Social Security and health care) if they want to continue […]
[…] that’s the lesson that developing nations should […]
[…] that’s the lesson that developing nations should […]
[…] moral of the story is that there’s no substitute for free markets and small […]
[…] with the theory of “convergence,” which is the (mostly true) idea that poor nations should grow faster than rich […]
[…] instance, convergence is a sensible theory, but the rate of convergence (or divergence!) is very dependent on the degree to which nations have good policy (or bad […]
[…] (atualmente, o produto per capta nos EUA é mais de cinco vezes maior do que na China)? Ou, como muitas outras economias emergentes, eles baterão em um teto e aí começarão a […]
[…] this is because I’m a policy wonk, but I also like budget numbers because they generally provide strong evidence for my philosophical belief in small government and spending […]
[…] poor nations such as Botwsana and China can enjoy meaningful gains with partial economic […]
[…] poor nations such as Botwsana and China can enjoy meaningful gains with partial economic […]
[…] if Brazil wants to break out of the “middle-income trap,” it needs to follow the tried-and-true recipe for growth and prosperity (what used to be […]
[…] an economic perspective, it’s further evidence that government intervention leads to a misallocation of resources. And that inevitably means living standards will be lower than they would be if markets were […]
[…] Mitchell, Daniel j. “If Poor Nations Want Economic Convergence and Capital Accumulation, They Need Good Policy.” International Liberty, 29 Mar. 2015, https://danieljmitchell.wordpress.com/2015/03/29/if-poor-nations-want-economic-convergence-and-capit… […]
[…] de la gente normal en Venezuela. Lo que hace especialmente poderosos estos números es que la teoría de la convergencia supone que la diferencia entre naciones ricas y naciones pobres debería disminuir. Pero las […]
[…] Free markets and limited government are a tried-and-true recipe for growth and prosperity. […]
[…] is why I share so many examples showing how market-oriented jurisdictions out-perform statist nations over multi-decade […]
[…] economic theory holds that incomes in countries should converge. In the real world, however, that only happens if governments don’t create too many obstacles to […]
[…] I think comparative economics can be very enlightening, I’m quite pleased to see a new study by David Burton of the Heritage Foundation, which uses […]
[…] Assuming, of course, that they have decent policy. […]
[…] a chart showing how Argentina is de-converging, which is remarkably depressing since conventional theory tells us that poor nations should be catching up with rich […]
[…] P.S. If you want other compelling examples that show – over multiple decades – the superior performance of market-oriented nations, click here and here. […]
[…] International development experts often write about a “middle-income trap.” […]
[…] a slam-dunk success. Based on data from the World Bank, here’s a look at how China and India started converging with the United States after opening to the world […]
[…] I give speeches on the importance of public policy, I frequently share data showing that pro-market nations are relatively prosperous when compared to countries with statist […]
[…] es mi suposición. Lo último que quiere la izquierda es que la gente entienda que las naciones pobres solo se convierten en naciones ricas con mercados libres y gobiernos […]
[…] theory is quite reasonable, but I’ve pointed out that decent public policy (i.e., free markets and small government) is a necessary condition for […]
[…] my guess. The last thing the left wants is for people to understand that poor nations only become rich nations with free markets and small […]
[…] my guess. The last thing the left wants is for people to understand that poor nations only become rich nations with free markets and small […]
[…] my guess. The last thing the left wants is for people to understand that poor nations only become rich nations with free markets and small […]
[…] Serbia tiene la capacidad de “converger“, pero eso no ocurrirá sin la liberalización […]
[…] discuss convergence, I often share the data on Hong Kong and Singapore because those jurisdictions have caught up to the United States. But I make sure to explain that the convergence was only possible because of good […]
[…] Serbia has the capacity to “converge,” but that won’t happen without economic […]
[…] Serbia has the capacity to “converge,” but that won’t happen without economic […]
[…] reverse is true as well. There are many nations that used to be poor, but now are rich thanks to the right kind of […]
[…] in Shenyang. My topic today was “Real-World Examples,” which gave me an opportunity to share many of the charts I’ve developed showing how market-oriented nations enjoy much more long-run […]
[…] tema de hoy era “Ejemplos del mundo real”, lo que ha dado la oportunidad de compartir muchos de los gráficos que he desarrollado mostrando cómo las naciones orientadas al mercado disfrutan de mucho más éxito a largo […]
[…] in Shenyang. My topic today was “Real-World Examples,” which gave me an opportunity to share many of the charts I’ve developed showing how market-oriented nations enjoy much more long-run […]
[…] My topic today was “Real-World Examples,” which gave me an opportunity to share many of the charts I’ve developed showing how market-oriented nations enjoy much more long-run […]
[…] in Shenyang. My topic today was “Real-World Examples,” which gave me an opportunity to share many of the charts I’ve developed showing how market-oriented nations enjoy much more long-run […]
[…] I’ve explained that China has enjoyed reasonably impressive growth in recent decades thanks to pro-market reforms. But I’ve also pointed out that further economic liberalization is needed if China wants to avoid the middle-income trap. […]
[…] I’ve explained that China has enjoyed reasonably impressive growth in recent decades thanks to pro-market reforms. But I’ve also pointed out that further economic liberalization is needed if China wants to avoid the middle-income trap. […]
[…] tema de hoy era “Ejemplos del mundo real”, lo que ha dado la oportunidad de compartir muchos de los gráficos que he desarrollado mostrando cómo las naciones orientadas al mercado disfrutan de mucho más éxito a largo […]
[…] My topic today was “Real-World Examples,” which gave me an opportunity to share many of the charts I’ve developed showing how market-oriented nations enjoy much more long-run […]
[…] again, I give a standard caveat about economists and forecasting. And I also explain the principle of convergence so the audience understands it’s more difficult for a rich country to achieve very high […]
[…] States, Slovakia has enjoyed reasonably strong growth that has resulted in considerable “convergence” to western living […]
[…] evidence that global economic liberty has increased over the past few decades. And for those who care about evidence, there’s a slam-dunk argument that smaller government means more […]
[…] el estatismo es que sencillamente no funciona. Las naciones con más gobierno y más intervención normalmente funcionan peor comparadas con países similares en otros aspectos, pero con gobiernos pequeños y mercados […]
[…] statism is that it simply doesn’t work. Nations with bigger government and more intervention routinely under-perform compared to otherwise-similar countries with small government and free […]
[…] statism is that it simply doesn’t work. Nations with bigger government and more intervention routinely under-perform compared to otherwise-similar countries with small government and free […]
[…] statism is that it simply doesn’t work. Nations with bigger government and more intervention routinely under-perform compared to otherwise-similar countries with small government and free […]
[…] statism is that it simply doesn’t work. Nations with bigger government and more intervention routinely under-perform compared to otherwise-similar countries with small government and free […]
[…] statism is that it simply doesn’t work. Nations with bigger government and more intervention routinely under-perform compared to otherwise-similar countries with small government and free […]
[…] que hace especialmente poderosos estos números es que la teoría de la convergencia supone que la diferencia entre naciones ricas y naciones pobres debería disminuir. Pero las […]
[…] mostra que nações em desenvolvimento podem experimentar “convergência ” e se juntar ao primeiro mundo se elas adotarem boas […]
[…] don’t need to be an economist to understand why Sanders and Corbyn are wrong. Normal people can look at how fast various nations grow (or don’t grow) and draw the appropriate […]
[…] If you’re not familiar with technological jargon, “distance from the technological frontier” is basically a way of saying that nations with lots of bad policy – and thus lots of misallocated and/or underutilized labor and capital – probably have more ability to enjoy fast growth. Sort of a version of convergence theory. […]
[…] makes these numbers especially powerful is that convergence theory assumes that the gap between rich nations and poor nations should shrink. Yet statist policies are […]
[…] become rich in the modern era. Yes, some other countries have grown, but they are not on a path to converge with rich […]
[…] that’s to be expected. Convergence theory tells us that poorer places should grow faster than richer places (at least in the absence of unusual […]
[…] I don’t want to focus on my remarks (much of which will be old news to regular readers). Instead, let’s look at the some of the information in a speech by Professor Tony Makin of […]
[…] I don’t want to focus on my remarks (much of which will be old news to regular readers). Instead, let’s look at the some of the information in a speech by Professor Tony Makin of […]
[…] data and I try to avoid this methodological sin by looking at multi-year periods (or, even better, multi-decade periods) when analyzing various […]
[…] is a good point. As I explained two years ago, full convergence is very difficult. North America and Western Europe became rich in part because […]
[…] policy (or if both benefit from a policy), then the world clearly isn’t zero-sum. And we now from voluminous evidence, of course, that the world isn’t that […]
[…] is a cornucopia of evidence that nations with comparatively small and non-intrusive governments are much more prosperous than countries with lots of taxes, spending, and […]
[…] I repeatedly argue, if you want good economic results, you need good […]
[…] economic developments keep demonstrating (over and over again) that big government and high taxes are not a recipe for prosperity. That can’t be very […]
[…] Fortunately, we avoided that outcome and instead enjoyed a reduction in inequality caused by better policy and growth-driven convergence. […]
[…] Fortunately, we avoided that outcome and instead enjoyed a reduction in inequality caused by better policy and growth-driven convergence. […]
[…] a table showing how nations rose or fell, relative to other OECD nations, since then. Based on convergence theory, one would expect to see that poorer nations enjoyed the biggest relative gains, while richer […]
[…] makes this especially noteworthy is that convergence theory says that poorer nations should automatically catch up to richer nations. Yet Europe’s […]
[…] true when comparing nations. And it’s also true when comparing states. That must be a source of endless frustration an […]
[…] of free markets over statism. And I’m probably annoyingly relentless about disseminating examples of good and bad policy from around the world (my version of “teachable […]
[…] of free markets over statism. And I’m probably annoyingly relentless about disseminating examples of good and bad policy from around the world (my version of “teachable […]
[…] trying to educate people about the superiority of free enterprise over statism, I generally show them long-run data comparing market-oriented jurisdictions with those that have state-driven economies. Here are some […]
[…] should still strive for perfection, of course, and at least hope for good or very good policy. After all, there’s a big difference in the long run between an economy that grows 5 percent […]
[…] I’ve put together all sorts of long-run comparisons to show that free markets produce much better results than […]
[…] I’ve put together all sorts of long-run comparisons to show that free markets produce much better results than […]
[…] I’ve put together all sorts of long-run comparisons to show that free markets produce much better results than […]
[…] even if the title is boring, this Paradox makes a critical point. The poor nations that have become rich nations in recent decades did not rely on handouts and […]
[…] even if the title is boring, this Paradox makes a critical point. The poor nations that have become rich nations in recent decades did not rely on handouts and […]
[…] also are good, Andy explains, because they create natural experiments that allow us the compare the success of market-oriented jurisdictions with the failure of statist […]
[…] Kong didn’t just converge with one of the world’s richest countries, which by itself would be a remarkable and unusual achievement. It actually became […]
[…] economic output in America is more than five times higher than it is in China)? Or will China, like many other developing/transition economies, hit a ceiling and then begin to […]
[…] We’ve enjoyed nearly twice as much growth as Europe and almost three times as much growth as Japan. Which is remarkable since those countries aren’t as rich as the United States and they should grow faster according to convergence theory. […]
[…] Eastern European nations can engage in more reform to improve overall economic liberty and thus boost growth […]
[…] repeatedly made this argument by comparing the economic performance of market-oriented jurisdictions and statist […]
[…] repeatedly made this argument by comparing the economic performance of market-oriented jurisdictions and statist […]
[…] bottom line is that economic liberty works while left-wing ideologies (all based on coercion) don’t work, so let’s use whatever […]
[…] really. The countries that embraced free markets grew much faster than the ones that didn’t. See If Poor Nations Want Economic Convergence and Capital Accumulation, They Need Good Policy at Dan Mitchell’s blog. Example capitalist nations that improved much faster than ‘big […]
[…] simply add a few observations. One of the reasons I often compare market-oriented nations and government-oriented nations is to highlight how countries are more […]
[…] close out my presentation, I zipped through several slides showing how nations with pro-market policies enjoy faster long-run growth than countries burdened by statism. The obvious conclusion is that even modest improvements in economic growth, if sustained for a […]
[…] close out my presentation, I zipped through several slides showing how nations with pro-market policies enjoy faster long-run growth than countries burdened by statism. The obvious conclusion is that even modest improvements in economic growth, if sustained for a […]
[…] evidence from all over the world is that this is not a recipe for convergence with rich […]
[…] evidence from all over the world is that this is not a recipe for convergence with rich […]
[…] Kong didn’t just converge with one of the world’s richest countries, which by itself would be a remarkable and unusual achievement. It actually became […]
[…] simply add a few observations. One of the reasons I often compare market-oriented nations and government-oriented nations is to highlight how countries are more […]
[…] leans in the direction of markets or whether it is burdened by a lot of statism. And it allows for meaningful comparisons between nations since it relies on global data […]
[…] leans in the direction of markets or whether it is burdened by a lot of statism. And it allows for meaningful comparisons between nations since it relies on global data […]
[…] simply add a few observations. One of the reasons I often compare market-oriented nations and government-oriented nations is to highlight how countries are more […]
[…] enjoy great progress while nations that veer in the other direction suffer economic decline, as vividly demonstrated by comparisons such as the relative performance of Hong Kong and […]
[…] Kong didn’t just converge with one of the world’s richest countries, which by itself would be a remarkable and unusual achievement. It actually became […]
[…] it shows that nations from the developing world can experience “convergence” and join the first world if they adopt good policies. They don’t even need great policies. The […]
[…] it shows that nations from the developing world can experience “convergence” and join the first world if they adopt good […]
[…] shouldn’t even exist. Everywhere big government has been tried, it has failed. And we have reams of evidence that free-market economies dramatically out-perform statist […]
[…] we have reams of evidence that free-market economies dramatically out-perform statist […]
[…] we have reams of evidence that free-market economies dramatically out-perform statist […]
[…] we have reams of evidence that free-market economies dramatically out-perform statist […]
[…] Kong didn’t just converge with one of the world’s richest countries, which by itself would be a remarkable and unusual achievement. It actually became […]
[…] just converge with one of the world’s richest countries, which by itself would be a remarkable and unusual achievement. It actually became […]
[…] differences in growth can have enormous implications for a nation’s long-run […]
[…] differences in growth can have enormous implications for a nation’s long-run […]
[…] differences in growth can have enormous implications for a nation’s long-run […]
[…] differences in growth can have enormous implications for a nation’s long-run […]
[…] differences in growth can have enormous implications for a nation’s long-run […]
[…] economy and we don’t have a lot of “low-hanging fruit” to exploit. Simply stated, it’s much easier to boost labor productivity in a poor […]
[…] we don’t have a lot of “low-hanging fruit” to exploit. Simply stated, it’s much easier to boost labor productivity in a poor […]
[…] South Africa. These so-called BRICS nations were enjoying some decent growth at the time, but I was not optimistic about their long-run prospects because they all suffered from too much statism according to the rankings from Economic Freedom of […]
[…] I’m not just talking about left-wing support for statist policies that dampen growth and hurt all income classes. In some cases their preferred policies result in the transfer of income and wealth from the poor […]
[…] I’m not just talking about left-wing support for statist policies that dampen growth and hurt all income classes. In some cases their preferred policies result in the transfer of income and wealth from the poor […]
[…] There are many real-world examples of how nations with sensible public policy enjoy very strong growth, leading to huge increases in […]
[…] Now if you don’t agree with Bono, you could look at Daniel Mitchell’s version of this answer here: If Poor Nations Want Economic Convergence and Capital Accumulation, They Need Good Policy: […]
[…] Or how could anyone pick socialism (or any other form of coercive statism) after reviewing how market-based economies out-perform big-government economies? […]
[…] Or how could anyone pick socialism (or any other form of coercive statism) after reviewing how market-based economies out-perform big-government economies? […]
[…] this is because I’m a policy wonk, but I also like budget numbers because they generally provide strong evidence for my philosophical belief in small government and spending […]
[…] why I repeatedly show how market-oriented jurisdictions out-perform statist […]
[…] why I repeatedly show how market-oriented jurisdictions out-perform statist […]
[…] this is because I’m a policy wonk, but I also like budget numbers because they generally provide strong evidence for my philosophical belief in small government and spending […]
[…] this is because I’m a policy wonk, but I also like budget numbers because they generally provide strong evidence for my philosophical belief in small government and spending […]
[…] is because I’m a policy wonk, but I also like budget numbers because they generally provide strong evidence for my philosophical belief in small government and spending […]
[…] that follow that approach vastly out-perform the countries that choose […]
[…] that follow that approach vastly out-perform the countries that choose […]
[…] As a general rule, I think ordinary people are sympathetic to limited government, particularly if you have a chance to dispassionately explain how nations with good policy routinely out-perform countries with bad policy. […]
[…] the second group of statists should be persuadable. That’s why I share so many comparisons of nations with smaller government and freer markets versus countries with bigger government and […]
[…] is that he is in a position of influence and he’s using that power to promote policies that will reduce prosperity. And poor people will be the biggest victims, as I explained in this BBC […]
[…] Here’s an interesting variation on the “No True Scotsman” fallacy: people who are anti-free market will try to rule out typical examples that libertarian/free marketers bring up. The common examples are Hong Kong, Singapore, Taiwan and Ireland as nations that pursued free market policies. See Dan Mitchell’s post on economic convergence here. […]
[…] of the reasons I repeatedly compare market-oriented countries with statist nations is to show that even minor differences in growth, if sustained over time, can have enormous impact […]
[…] of the reasons I repeatedly compare market-oriented countries with statist nations is to show that even minor differences in growth, if sustained over time, can have enormous impact […]
[…] of the reasons I repeatedly compare market-oriented countries with statist nations is to show that even minor differences in growth, if sustained over time, can have enormous impact […]
[…] we want the third world to converge with rich nations, they need to follow the policies that enabled rich nations to become rich in the first […]
[…] other words, when you do apples to apples comparisons, either of peoples or nations, you find that smaller government and free markets lead to more […]
[…] completely unreasonable statists blindly assert, notwithstanding all the evidence around the world, that bigger government and more intervention are actually good for […]
[…] many leftists who genuinely seem to think the economy is a fixed pie. And they seem impervious to all the evidence that free markets and small government are the way to achieve broadly shared […]
[…] utter nonsense. The economy is not a fixed pie and there is overwhelming evidence that nations with better policy grow faster and create more […]
[…] statism really compassionate when it means less long-run growth and lower living standards for ordinary […]
[…] completely unreasonable statists blindly assert, notwithstanding all the evidence around the world, that bigger government and more intervention are actually good for […]
[…] also use real-world examples to show how some nations become much richer than other nations within just a few decades because of […]
[…] Shifting to another topic, I like to share examples of how some nations enjoy faster growth than others, mostly because these comparison invariably […]
For those who might have missed my earlier comment, I highly recommend the book “Thieves of State” by Sarah Chayes. She describes how corruption has thrown the Middle East into turmoil.
[…] WAIT, THERE’S MORE… […]
Would you forward a copy of this to each of our representatives??? SOMEONE up there should know SOME economics and the importance of a balanced budget….. currently I don’t believe there is ANYONE, with the possible exception of Rand Paul, who realizes if we sell our country out now, there WILL be no tomorrow as we know it!!!
I think you might also have to include graft and corruption as a killer of ecomonic growth.
[…] By Dan Mitchell […]