During my early years in public policy, back in the late 1980s, I repeatedly crossed swords with people who argued that Washington should have more power over the economy so that the United States could compete with Japan, which supposedly was an economic juggernaut because of “industrial policy” directed by wise and far-sighted bureaucrats at the Ministry of International Trade and Industry.
Given Japan’s subsequent multi-decade slump, it certainly seems like I was right to warn against giving American politicians the power to pick winners and losers.
But not everybody learned from that experience. In the words of Yogi Berra, “It’s deja vu all over again,” only this time we’re supposed to be terrified because the Chinese government wants to subsidize and promote certain industries as part of “Made in China 2025”.
At the risk of understatement, I’m not scared.
Yes, China has enjoyed some impressive growth since it partially liberalized its economy in the late 1900s, but it will remain far behind the United States unless – as I recently explained on CNBC – there is a new wave of free-market reforms.
Needless to say, a government initiative to favor certain industries is hardly a step in that direction.
Some Chinese policy makers even realize that it’s counterproductive to give that kind of power to politicians and bureaucrats.
Here are some excerpts from a report in the South China Morning Post.
“Made in China 2025” has been a waste of taxpayers’ money, China’s former finance minister Lou Jiwei has said…“[Made in China] 2025 has been a lot of talking but very little was done,” Lou, chairman of the National Council for Social Security Fund, said on Wednesday…
“those industries are not predictable and the government should not have thought it had the ability to predict what is not foreseeable.” …“The negative effect of [the plan] is to have wasted taxpayers’ money.” He suggested the market should have played a greater role in developing the industries that MIC2025 was designed to push. “The [resources] should have been allocated by the market; the government should give the market a decisive role,” Lou said. “Why has the government pushed so hard on this strategy? [Hi-tech industry prospects] can all change in a few years, it is too unforeseeable.”
Sounds like Mr. Lou learned from Obama’s Solyndra fiasco that cronyism doesn’t work.
But some of his colleagues still need to be educated.
Made in China 2025 (MIC2025) strategy, Beijing’s blueprint for tech supremacy. …Since the plan’s launch in 2015,
the government has poured money into MIC2025 to try to turn a number of domestic industries – including artificial intelligence, pharmaceuticals and electric vehicles – into global leaders by 2025. …Lou said: “It [the strategy] should not have been done that way anyway. I was against it from the start, I did not agree very much with it.
I hope senior government officials change their minds about this harmful exercise in central planning.
Not because I’m afraid it will work, but rather because I like China and I want the country to prosper. The partial reforms from last century produced great results for China, including huge reductions in poverty.
Additional reforms could lead to mass prosperity. But that won’t happen if the Chinese government tries to control the allocation of resources.
Let’s close with a big-picture look at central planning and industrial policy, starting with the common-sense observation that there are degrees of intervention.
Here’s my back-of-the-envelope perspective. We have examples of nations, such as the Soviet Union, where the government had near-total control over the allocation of labor and capital. And I suppose Hong Kong would be the closest example of a laissez-faire jurisdiction. And then there’s everything in between.
I’ve already shared two great videos on government planning versus the market. I strongly recommend this Prager University video, narrated by Professor Burton Folsom, on the failure of government-dictated investment. And also this video narrated by Professor Russ Roberts, which shows how a decentralized market efficiently provides a bounty to consumers.
Here’s a third, which celebrates the work of the late Don Lavoie, one of my professors when I studied at George Mason University.
By the way, there is a terrible flaw in the video. The photo that appears at 1:38 shows select faculty and students in 1987. Why is that a flaw? For the simple reason that I was part of the photo but got cropped out in the video.
P.S. Some people worry that China’s industrial policy will have a negative spillover effect on the United States because American companies will lose market share to the subsidized Chinese companies. That’s a legitimate concern and American officials should use the World Trade Organization to counter mercantilist policies.
P.P.S. To my dismay, some people don’t want China to become a rich nation. I assume those people are hoping China follows the advice of the OECD and IMF.
[…] are people who want government ownership, central planning, and price controls. Sort of like Cuba, North Korea, or the former Soviet […]
[…] are people who want government ownership, central planning, and price controls. Sort of like Cuba, North Korea, or the former Soviet […]
[…] comment, socialism is an economic system based on misguided policies such as government ownership, central planning, and price controls. Communism is a political system based on dictatorship and […]
[…] not. Today’s industrial policy is cronyism, not full-fledged central planning. But it is nonetheless a bad idea to move in the wrong […]
[…] Chips law is a role model. But if industrial policy was a good idea, why did Japan stagnate? Why hasChina’s growth […]
[…] Chips law is a role model. But if industrial policy was a good idea, why did Japan stagnate? Why has China’s growth […]
[…] China is suffering in part because of that form of […]
[…] For what it’s worth, my gut instinct is that cronyism is a much bigger problem in China’s economy that we see in the data from the WSJ and the […]
[…] For what it’s worth, my gut instinct is that cronyism is a much bigger problem in China’s economy that we see in the data from the WSJ and the […]
[…] For what it’s worth, my gut instinct is that cronyism is a much bigger problem in China’s economy that we see in the data from the WSJ and the […]
[…] illustrated by this video, letting politicians distort the economy is a recipe for stagnation and […]
[…] is an unacceptable nominee for her support for hard-core socialist policies such as central planningand government control of […]
[…] Ms. Omarova is an unacceptable nominee for her support for hard-core socialist policies such as central planning and government control of […]
[…] other words, industrial policy is backfiring on […]
[…] socialism (government ownership, central planning, and price controls) is an utter failure and is almost nonexistent today (only in a few […]
[…] But from a big-picture perspective, all that really happened is that China went from terrible policy (Maoist communism) to bad policy (best described as mass cronyism). […]
[…] the main points are 1) that China is no threat to overtake the United States, and 2) that copying that nation’s industrial policy would be a […]
[…] we’re using the technical definition of socialism (government ownership, central planning, and price controls), there’s no difference. At least with regards to […]
[…] be fair, not everything in the report is nonsense. The IMF is correctly skeptical of China’s industrial policy, and the bureaucrats also understand that protectionism is economically […]
[…] a technical definition of socialism based on policies such as government ownership, central planning, and price controls, and a casual definition of socialism based on policies such […]
[…] there’s a technical definition of socialism based on policies such as government ownership, central planning, and price controls, and a casual definition of socialism based on policies such as punitive tax […]
[…] we’re looking at the technical definition of socialism (government ownership, central planning, and price controls) or the casual definition of socialism (punitive tax rates, welfare state, […]
[…] pointing out we won’t get that happy outcome if China persists is following bad ideas such as central planning and industrial […]
[…] accompanied by central planning and price […]
[…] technical definition of socialism is an economic system based on government ownership, central planning, and price […]
[…] why is better to be on the correct side of this spectrum. In other words, as far from Soviet-style central planning as possible (I used to cite Hong Kong as an example of laissez-faire, but that may no longer be […]
[…] que hay una diferencia entre la forma en que los economistas lo definen (propiedad del gobierno, planificación central y control de precios) y la forma en que la gente normal lo define (muchos impuestos, […]
[…] nations are not socialist. As I’ve also pointed out, there’s no government ownership, central planning, and price controls in nations such as Sweden and […]
[…] Hayek – to explain why that approach (genuine socialism, meaning government ownership, central planning, and price controls) was doomed to […]
[…] Given that per-capita living standards are much lower in China than they are in the United States, I’m baffled that Schwab thinks it’s a good idea to move halfway toward the decrepit Chinese model of cronyism and industrial policy. […]
[…] Our prosperity is a result of the invisible hand (spontaneous order) rather than central planning. […]
[…] que hay una diferencia entre la forma en que los economistas lo definen (propiedad del gobierno, planificación central y control de precios) y la forma en que la gente normal lo define (muchos impuestos, […]
[…] socialism and communism are the same. They’re both based on government ownership, central planning, and price […]
[…] of the implications of this work is that central planning is not […]
[…] point out that there’s a difference between how economists define it (government ownership, central planning, and price controls) and how normal people define it (lots of taxes, redistribution, and […]
[…] la diferencia entre la definición técnica de socialismo (propiedad del gobierno, planificación central, controles de precios) y la definición cotidiana (mucha redistribución), me pregunto si […]
[…] point out that there’s a difference between how economists define it (government ownership, central planning, and price controls) and how normal people define it (lots of taxes, redistribution, and […]
[…] been socialist. By world standards, there’s basically no history of government ownership, central planning, or price […]
[…] about people on the left not understanding the real definition of socialism (government ownership, central planning, and price controls), so this next meme appealed to […]
[…] similar to what I’ve written, so let’s hope that China returns to the policy of economic liberalization that led to genuine […]
[…] In other words, the U.S. is moving in the wrong direction on my “Industrial Policy Spectrum.” […]
[…] In other words, the U.S. is moving in the wrong direction on my “Industrial Policy Spectrum.” […]
[…] is outright government ownership and control of business (along with other policies such as central planning and price […]
[…] is outright government ownership and control of business (along with other policies such as central planning and price […]
[…] Does this imply the technical meaning of socialism, involving government ownership, central planning, and price controls? If so, then world history suggests the correct answer is […]
[…] Does this imply the technical meaning of socialism, involving government ownership, central planning, and price controls? If so, then world history suggests the correct answer is […]
[…] P.P.S. Discouragingly, there are folks in the United States (advocates of ideas such as “national conservatism” and “common-good capitalism“) who think the United States should mimic aspects of China’s failed industrial policy. […]
[…] you want prosperity, it’s not a good idea to have central planning and other features of […]
[…] own and operate companies (the “means of production“). Such an approach also requires central planning and price […]
[…] debate – As I’ve repeatedly noted, genuine socialism involves government ownership, central planning, and price controls. Economists from the Austrian school, such as Mises, were the ones who […]
[…] two cents is that state-directed investment is a big problem, and it is an indirect cause of bad trade relations with the rest of the […]
[…] some Republican politicians are promoting a version of central planning called “industrial […]
[…] fixate on the trade deficit. More important, economic liberalization presumably would mean less central planning and cronyism, thus mitigating the concern that Chinese companies are using subsidies to gain an unfair […]
[…] Trump doesn’t understand trade and China’s leaders don’t want to give up their grip on the allocation of capital. So I’m not holding my breath waiting for a good […]
[…] much statism. Simply stated, the government has too much control over the allocation of labor and […]
[…] to be more accurate (since he presumably didn’t have any views about government ownership, central planning, or price controls), he wasn’t a […]
[…] all intents and purposes, the GND is a form of central planning. Not full Soviet style steering of the economy, but nonetheless a step in that […]
[…] that claim. The Nordic nations don’t have any of the policies – government ownership, central planning, or price controls – that are characteristics of a socialist […]
[…] people, when they talk about socialism, are referring to government ownership, central planning, and price […]
[…] is an economic system based on government ownership of the means of production, augmented by central planning, and price […]
[…] part, I wanted to show that genuine socialists, with their advocacy of government ownership, central planning, and price controls, aren’t really the same as other leftists (and I’ve made the […]
[…] firm understanding of socialism. Many of them don’t realize it implies government ownership, central planning, and price controls. Heck, some of them probably think the market-oriented Nordic welfare states […]
[…] he’s not even true to his socialist ideology. Rather than promoting government ownership, central planning, and price controls, he has behaved like a conventional left-wing politician. Indeed, there was […]
[…] hard-core socialist. A real socialist who would move the country toward government ownership, central planning and price […]
[…] Second, here are some excerpts from an Atlantic column about why it is difficult to alter China’s misguided approach. […]
[…] actual socialism — i.e., government ownership. And that presumably means he additionally helps central planning and price […]
[…] he wants real socialism — i.e., government ownership. And that presumably means he also supports central planning and price […]
[…] he wants real socialism (i.e., government ownership). And that presumably means he also supports central planning and price […]
[…] people still adhere to the technical definition, which means government ownership, central planning, and price controls. While others assume that socialism is high tax rates and lots of […]
[…] country. As I wrote, “There’s plenty of bad policy, but no government ownership, no central planning, and no price […]
[…] use the technical definition. There’s plenty of bad policy, but no government ownership, no central planning, and no price […]
[…] be sure, China still needs a lot of reform. It’s only ranked #107 according the latest edition of Economic Freedom of […]
[…] These penalties and preferences are both morally troubling (rampant cronyism) and economically damaging (back-door methods of central planning). […]
[…] These penalties and preferences are both morally troubling (rampant cronyism) and economically damaging (back-door methods of central planning). […]
[…] nations aren’t technically socialist (i.e., they don’t have government ownership, central planning, price […]
[…] Under Soviet rule, Czechoslovakia was genuine socialism (i.e., government ownership, central planning, price controls), which obviously is more damaging than what many people think of today as […]
[…] the difference between the technical definition of socialism (government ownership, central planning, price controls) and the everyday definition (lots of redistribution), I’m wondering whether I […]
[…] the difference between the technical definition of socialism (government ownership, central planning, price controls) and the everyday definition (lots of redistribution), I’m wondering […]
[…] the difference between the technical definition of socialism (government ownership, central planning, price controls) and the everyday definition (lots of redistribution), I’m wondering whether […]
[…] actually practice socialism since there is no government ownership of the means of production, no central planning, and no government-dictated […]
[…] prefer the technical definition, which involves government ownership of the means of production, central planning, and government-dictated prices. But most people assume it simply means big government, in which […]
Please see my recent paper on MIDAs in China, Professor Mitchell.
https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/full/10.1111/grow.12230
I endorse your position on industry policy or Made in China 2025. In fact, Hayek’s classic works including ‘Collective Economic Planning'(1934), The Road to Serfdom'(1944), ‘The Fatal Conceit'(1988), have told the decision makers and scholars that central planning can’t succeed finally. My paper on MIDAs also testified the judgment. Lou Jiwei in your blog was a follower of the reformer, former premier Zhu Rongji.
In fact, U.S. government, its officials and American people should not fear or worry about that plan. The probability of success is less than 50% if it is pushed by industrial policy or subsidy.
Hinder? Based upon the history Chinese development policies have been murderous.