When I wrote last week about “societal capital” as a key determinant of long-run prosperity, I didn’t realize I would generate a lot of feedback. Including several requests for more information.
Which creates a small problem since the field is so large that it’s difficult to provide an overview.
If people were asking questions on the flat tax, Laffer Curve, or the economic impact of government spending, I could give succinct and targeted responses. On the topic of social capital, by contrast, I almost don’t know where to start.
The first thing I should say is that scholars have been addressing these issues for centuries, even if in some cases they didn’t use the phrase “social capital” and instead talked about tradition, culture, ethics, morality, or civic attitudes.
Many people know Adam Smith wrote An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, but he also wrote The Theory of Moral Sentiments in the 1700s, and that book deals with issues relating to social capital.
Or consider the work of Alexis de Tocqueville, who wrote about social capital in Democracy in America in the 1800s. More recently, in the 1970s, Friedrich Hayek discussed ethics and attitudes as part of his three-volume masterpiece on Law, Legislation, and Liberty.
Moving into the 21st Century, the issue of “culture” and economics also was the subject of an in-depth online symposium at the Cato Institute in 2006. Here’s some of what Lawrence Harrison wrote.
Some economists have confronted culture and found it helpful in understanding economic development. Perhaps the broadest statement comes from the pen of David Landes: “Max Weber was right. If we learn anything from the history of economic development, it is that culture makes almost all the difference.” Elaborating on Landes’s theme, Japanese economist Yoshihara Kunio writes, “One reason Japan developed is that it had a culture suitable for it. The Japanese attached importance to (1) material pursuits; (2) hard work; (3) saving for the future; (4) investment in education; and (5) community values.” …More broadly, the analysis of religions suggests that Protestant, Jewish, and Confucian societies do better than Catholic, Islamic, and Orthodox Christian societies because they substantially share the progress-prone Economic Behavior values of the typology whereas the lagging religions tend toward the progress-resistant values. Symbolic of this divide is the persistent ambivalence of the Catholic Church toward market economics… But religion is not the only source of progress-prone economic behavior: the Basques are highly entrepreneurial and highly Catholic; and Chile, boasting the most successful sustained economic performance in Latin America, is also the most Catholic.
And here are portions of Gregory Clark’s contribution.
The standard economist emphasizes that stability, incentives, and laissez-faire are all the magic needed for riches. …attempts to introduce culture into economic discussions so far have been generally either ad hoc, vacuous, blatantly false, or void of testability. …Weber, as is well known, thought that certain types of Protestant ideology were conducive to economic growth. …The Catholics of modern southern Germany, however, would think they have a thing or two to teach their Protestant compatriots of the north about the virtues of hard work and self-reliance. The dour and thrifty Calvinists of my native Scotland look with envy now at the successes of the Catholic Irish, and ask how they can emulate this. …Protestants on average may have values associated with economic growth, but that seems to have nothing to do with their specific theology. Lawrence Harrison may seem to escape some of this problem of identifying cultural variation by using a survey of 25 factors that purports to identify systematically the essential elements of cultures that promote high incomes and growth: universal progress cultures. He divides cultures into the “progress-prone” and the “progress-resistant.” In progress-prone societies, for example, people assert “I can influence my destiny.” In progress-resistant societies “fatalism” rules. Progress-prone societies have better economic performance. …The problem with both the Harrison and McClelland approaches is that the responses may reflect just the realities of the institutional framework people live within, rather than their cultural attitudes. A North Korean who reports “fatalism” or “resignation” is plausibly no different culturally from a South Korean who states “I can influence my destiny.”
My grad school classmate and now Professor Pete Boettke adds his two cents.
…we do need to have market prices to allocate resources efficiently. The “getting the prices right” mantra is not wrong, just incomplete. In order to get market prices, we do need to have private property rights and the enforcement of contracts. The “getting the institutions in place” mantra isn’t wrong either. Many of the significant advances in political economy during the 1990s, when the problems of socialist transition were at the forefront of professional and public policy attention, were related to a change of emphasis from “getting the prices right” to “getting the institutions in place.” …In economic terms, culture is a tool for the self-regulation of behavior, and as such it either lowers or raises the costs of enforcing the rules of the game. A free society works best when the need for policemen is least. If the rules of conduct correlated with high levels of economic well-being are viewed by a culture as illegitimate, then those rules will be violated unless there are strong monitors. The costs of monitoring may be so high that the social order cannot in fact be sustained. …Scholars such as Joel Moykr in The Levers of Riches have documented the great technological innovations that fueled growth during the Industrial Revolution, but Mokyr also documents the underlying belief systems and attitudes that had to be present for those innovations to be discovered, implemented, and put into common practice. Without that underlying cultural commitment to scientific discovery, innovation would have been stifled. We can say the same for beliefs and attitudes that undermine private property, mutually beneficial exchange, and commercial development. …Whatever advantages a culture may have, they will not be realized under bad institutions. And whatever disadvantages a culture may have, they will slowly erode, and the culture will improve, when people get to live under institutions of political and economic freedom. Culture can act as a constraint, but it is also a malleable constraint.
James Robinson uses China and Chile as examples that suggest good policies and institutions are key.
If the Chinese do well in Indonesia because they have such a good culture, then why is China one of the world’s poorest countries? …surely the culture which supposedly is conducive to prosperity in China is an old one and long predates the acceleration of growth which took place in the late 1970s. …culture was held constant and institutions and policies changed while growth accelerated. From this it seems to follow that the reasons countries are poor has nothing to do with culture but rather policies and institutions that do not create the right incentive environment. …What about Chile, the one Latin American success story? Lawrence Harrison argues that Chile has a unique culture, but then why did it manifest itself so recently? It is only since the mid-1980s that the growth path of Chile has distinguished it from other Latin American countries. …culture might matter, but doubters like me will not be convinced by the evidence here.
But this topic gets attention at places other than libertarian think tanks.
Here are some excerpts from a World Bank study looking at the degree to which culture matters for development.
In the abstract there is no doubt a general acceptance that a particular work ethic, a system of personal values and attitudes must have a role in guiding a population along a particular development path; indeed, how could it be otherwise? …Guiso, Sapienza and Zingales (2006) conducted a regression analysis combining survey and macroeconomic data across 53 countries and found that “a 10 percentage point increase in the share of people who think thriftiness is a value that should be taught to children is linked to a 1.3 percentage point increase in the national saving rate”. Tabellini (2010) also showed that European regions with a stronger belief in individual effort tend to have higher GDP per capita and GDP growth. …Lee Kuan Yew speaks of a set of values—“thrift, hard work, filial piety and loyalty to the extended family, and, most of all, the respect for scholarship and learning”—as having provided a powerful cultural backdrop for the development of East Asian countries… Max Weber famously made the case about the role of culture in development in his essay “The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism,” arguing that Protestantism promoted the rise of modern capitalism “by defining and sanctioning an ethic of everyday behavior that conduced to business success” comprising “hard work, honesty, seriousness, the thrifty use of money and time.
Last but not least, let’s consider some practical applications based on a recently published New York Times column by David Brooks.
Twenty-five years after the fall of the Berlin Wall, the biggest surprise is how badly most of the post-communist nations have done since. …In the bottom group are basket-case nations that haven’t even recovered the level of real income they had in 1990, as measured by real G.D.P. per capita. These failures include Ukraine, Georgia, Bosnia, Serbia and others — about 20 percent of the post-communist world. “Basically,” Milanovic writes, these “are countries with at least three to four wasted generations. …The next group includes those nations that are merely moderate failures, with per capita economic growth rates under 1.7 percent a year. These are nations like Russia and Hungary that continue to fall steadily behind the West — about 40 percent of the post-communist world by population. The third group includes those with growth rates between 1.7 percent and 1.9 percent. These countries, like the Czech Republic and Slovenia, are holding steady with the capitalist world. Finally there are the successes, the nations that are catching up. …There are only five countries that have emerged as successful capitalist economies: Albania, Poland, Belarus, Armenia and Estonia. To put it another way, only 10 percent of the people living in post-communist nations are living in a place that successfully made the transition to capitalism.
I wouldn’t necessarily have listed Albania and Belarus as success stories, but it’s certainly true that the countries that comprised the former Soviet Bloc have seen a lot of divergence.
Heck, check out this graph comparing Ukraine and Poland if you want a remarkable example.
The question is why did they behave differently?
Why did some countries succeed while others failed? First, leaders in some countries simply made better political decisions. Most of these countries enacted economic reforms, like deregulating prices and privatizing nationalized companies. Some nations like Estonia and Poland enacted reforms radically and quickly… The quick and radical group saw a slightly bigger output drop over the near term but much more prosperity over the long run. …Finally, and most important, there is the level of values. A nation’s economy is nestled in its moral ecology. Economic performance is tied to history, culture and psychology. …[Some] countries lacked this cultural brew. Worse, life was marked by fear, by arbitrary power, by suspicion that people are watching you, by distrust. People raised in this atmosphere of distrust have trouble forming companies and associations. They are more likely to be driven by a grab-what-you-can logic — a culture of corruption and appropriation. …The lesson of the past 25 years is that democratic prosperity is built on layers of small achievements 10,000 fathoms deep. Communism ripped at all that bottom-up society-making and damaged the psyches of its victims. Healing from those wounds is gradual.
So what’s the bottom line?
I’m not really sure, other than to assert that we will never triumph over statism if Americans think it is morally acceptable to live off their neighbors via the coercive power of government.
In many of my fiscal policy speeches, I explain that we face a major crisis because of demographics and poorly designed entitlement programs, but then tell audiences that we can solve the problem with structural program reforms.
To wrap things up, I often close with this Powerpoint slide. As you can see, the first two themes are very familiar to regular readers. Our problem is too much government spending and the solution is my Golden Rule of spending restraint.
But the third bullet point is really about societal capital.
In other words, we can share all sorts of evidence about how some nations grow faster with small government and free markets.
We can also highlight how statist policies slow growth.
But none of those arguments will mean much in the long run if people prefer to be wards of the state.
P.S. My concern with personal morality helps to explain why I think libertarians and social conservatives should be natural allies.
November 4, 2018 addendum: To be more precise, I’m now trying to use “societal capital” rather than “social capital.”
[…] Simply stated, the decline in labor force participation may be a sign of eroding societal capital. […]
[…] Simply stated, the decline in labor force participation may be a sign of eroding societal capital. […]
[…] An example of how big government erodes societal capital. […]
[…] An example of how big government erodes societal capital. […]
[…] But it’s increasingly difficult to feel optimistic about the long-run outlook for America’s societal capital. […]
[…] But it’s increasingly difficult to feel optimistic about the long-run outlook for America’s societal capital. […]
[…] But it’s increasingly difficult to feel optimistic about the long-run outlook for America’s societal capital. […]
[…] there’s another reason to be concerned about redistribution. I worry that it erodes societal capital (i.e., the traits such as work ethic, self reliance, etc, that are associated with successful […]
[…] is that the United States is uniquely individualistic, which I view as a very valuable form of societal capital (another great president shared that […]
[…] featured some of Milton Friedman’s wisdom from 50 years ago on how a high level of societal capital (work ethic, spirit of self-reliance, etc) is needed if we want to limit […]
[…] of understatement, I fear Robert Higgs is right and that today’s politicians (and today’s voters!) will choose the latter […]
[…] counteract that disturbing trend, he explains that we need a high level of “societal capital.” In other words, we need a self-reliant and ethical populace – i.e., people who realize it’s […]
[…] of understatement, I fear Robert Higgs is right and that today’s politicians (and today’s voters!) will choose the latter […]
[…] Second, here’s a cartoon that nicely captures why I think Biden’s agenda will erode the nation’s societal capital. […]
[…] counteract that disturbing trend, he explains that we need a high level of “societal capital.” In other words, we need a self-reliant and ethical populace – i.e., people who realize it’s […]
[…] featured some of Milton Friedman’s wisdom from 50 years ago on how a high level of societal capital (work ethic, spirit of self-reliance, etc) is needed if we want to limit […]
[…] Second, here’s a cartoon that nicely captures why I think Biden’s agenda will erode the nation’s societal capital. […]
[…] featured some of Milton Friedman’s wisdom from 50 years ago on how a high level of societal capital (work ethic, spirit of self-reliance, etc) is needed if we want to limit […]
[…] featured some of Milton Friedman’s wisdom from 50 years ago on how a high level of societal capital (work ethic, spirit of self-reliance, etc) is needed if we want to limit […]
[…] Second, here’s a cartoon that nicely captures why I think Biden’s agenda will erode the nation’s societal capital. […]
[…] In some sense, this is not just about economics. It’s also about preserving societal capital. […]
[…] In some sense, this is not just about economics. It’s also about preserving societal capital. […]
[…] Second, here’s a cartoon that nicely captures why I think Biden’s agenda will erode the nation’s societal capital. […]
[…] Maybe that’s a smart way of buying votes, but it will erode societal capital. […]
[…] Maybe that’s a smart way of buying votes, but it will erode societal capital. […]
[…] Maybe that’s a smart way of buying votes, but it will erode societal capital. […]
[…] Second, here’s a cartoon that nicely captures why I think Biden’s agenda will erode the nation’s societal capital. […]
[…] Second, here’s a cartoon that nicely captures why I think Biden’s agenda will erode the nation’s societal capital. […]
[…] Second, here’s a cartoon that nicely captures why I think Biden’s agenda will erode the nation’s societal capital. […]
[…] Maybe that’s a smart way of buying votes, but it will erode societal capital. […]
[…] Maybe that’s a smart way of buying votes, but it will erode societal capital. […]
[…] Maybe that’s a smart way of buying votes, but it will erode societal capital. […]
[…] undermine personal independence, the work ethic, the spirit of self reliance, and other traits that are critical for a successful society. And I also didn’t trust (for good reason) Yang’s claim that his scheme would replace […]
[…] it would undermine personal independence, the work ethic, the spirit of self reliance, and other traits that are critical for a successful society. And I also didn’t trust (for good reason) Yang’s claim that his scheme would replace […]
[…] of understatement, I fear Robert Higgs is right and that today’s politicians (and today’s voters!) will choose the latter […]
[…] also very interested in “societal capital,” which is the degree to which the people of a nation believe in values such as self […]
[…] featured some of Milton Friedman’s wisdom from 50 years ago on how a high level of societal capital (work ethic, spirit of self-reliance, etc) is needed if we want to limit […]
[…] featured some of Milton Friedman’s wisdom from 50 years ago on how a high level of societal capital (work ethic, spirit of self-reliance, etc) is needed if we want to limit […]
[…] featured some of Milton Friedman’s wisdom from 50 years ago on how a high level of societal capital (work ethic, spirit of self-reliance, etc) is needed if we want to limit […]
[…] featured some of Milton Friedman’s wisdom from 50 years ago on how a high level of societal capital (work ethic, spirit of self-reliance, etc) is needed if we want to limit […]
[…] column featured some of Milton Friedman’s wisdom from 50 years ago on how a high level of societal capital (work ethic, spirit of self-reliance, etc) is needed if we want to limit […]
[…] counteract that disturbing trend, he explains that we need a high level of “societal capital.” In other words, we need a self-reliant and ethical populace – i.e., people who […]
[…] is largely good news since it shows that America still enjoys a high degree of societal capital (work ethic, desire to earn rather than get handouts, […]
[…] And once there are too many people riding in the wagon of government dependency, it’s not easy to rejuvenate a nation’s social capital. […]
[…] us something more important – that these programs are especially bad because they erode societal capital. They teach people it’s okay to live off the government and that they don’t need to […]
[…] dependency mindset shows that societal capital has eroded, and it’s why I fear those nations have passed a tipping […]
[…] That has very serious economic consequences. Especially if it coincides with an erosion of societal capital. […]
[…] I worry that he’s right, particularly since redistribution erodes societal capital. […]
[…] about European-wide attitudes (though that also is something to worry about, given the erosion of societal capital), but rather the views of the European […]
[…] capital – I fear that there is a tipping point and that nations are doomed once people decide that it’s morally acceptable to use government coercion to live off the effort of […]
[…] argued that big government undermines charity, it undermines civil society, and that it undermines societal capital as […]
[…] the risk of understatement, I fear Robert Higgs is right and that today’s politicians (and today’s voters!) will choose the latter […]
[…] depend on good tax policy, and rule of law doesn’t magically materialize. You need a form of societal capital as the […]
[…] depend on good tax policy and rule of law doesn’t magically materialize. You need a form of societal capital as the […]
[…] appears to be a tragic example of what happens when societal capital erodes (or never gets established in the first place) and too many people in the country see […]
[…] when I think about “moral decay,” I’m focusing on the erosion of societal capital, not whether someone smokes pot or looks at a naked picture on the […]
[…] For what it’s worth, I don’t think western nations necessarily will collapse (though some almost certainly will depending on the degree to which societal capital has been destroyed). […]
[…] other words, even though it’s mathematically possible to fix the problems, the erosion of societal capital suggests that Greece may have reached the point of […]
[…] By contrast, a nation that trades the work ethic for universal handouts is taking a very risky gamble. […]
[…] By contrast, a nation that trades the work ethic for universal handouts is taking a very risky gamble. […]
[…] In other words, people is those states still have social capital or cultural capital. […]
[…] And once there are too many people riding in the wagon of government dependency, it’s not easy to rejuvenate a nation’s social capital. […]
[…] reliance, work, and individual responsibility. Characteristics that could be considered part of social capital or cultural […]
[…] other words, handouts from rich nations are destroying the social capital of […]
[…] One of the most insightful parts of the video was when Dennis pointed out that excessive government weakens character. Which is just another way of pointing out that statism erodes social capital. […]
[…] One of the most insightful parts of the video was when Dennis pointed out that excessive government weakens character. Which is just another way of pointing out that statism erodes social capital. […]
[…] the absence of societal ethics, it’s not a good idea to let two wolves and a sheep vote on what to have for lunch. It has […]
[…] also erodes the social capital of a people, telling them that individual initiative and success are somehow exploitative and […]
[…] also erodes the social capital of a people, telling them that individual initiative and success are somehow exploitative and […]
[…] A growing number of people figure out that it’s better to ride in the wagon rather than pull the wagon (i.e., erosion of social capital). […]
[…] Second, even if small government-oriented Republicans controlled Washington after the 2016 election, that might not change the nation’s long-run trend toward more dependency. […]
[…] his nation. Not only did he sabotage Argentina’s economy, he also apparently undermined the social capital of the country by somehow convincing a big chunk of the population that “Peronism” is […]
[…] in Baltimore, by contrast, are a short-run phenomenon exacerbated by factors such as a loss of social capital and potential police […]
[…] He’s a dirtbag who decided that it is perfectly okay to scam off taxpayers. When enough of his fellow citizens make the same choice, a society is in deep trouble. […]
[…] is spot on. A nation is far more likely to be successful if people have the right attitudes, what’s variously referred to as social capital, national character, cultural capital, […]
[…] is spot on. A nation is far more likely to be successful if people have the right attitudes, what’s variously referred to as social capital, national character, cultural capital, […]
[…] I agree, at least to the degree that she’s embracing the value of social capital. […]
social capital… is eroded by moral decay… the current system is geared toward socializing the next generation of Americans to support failed socialist policies… and lefty politics… it’s most evident in the public school system and in the national establishment media…
teach your children well…
Thanks, Dan, always start my day with at least one of your columns.
Let’s Play Two!
Personally I think that culture and policy/legislation DO work in tandem. Culture influences legislation, but legislation and policy also affect culture. Many immigrants to the US embraced American values, once they were placed in an environment where legislation and policy (or lack thereof) allowed them to prosper in self-reliance.
Redistribution (i.e. attempts to increase one’s standard of living by harvesting the work and efforts of his neighbors) erodes social capital, increases social entropy, and creates a mentality of dependence, flatter effort-reward curves, less motivation towards exceptionalism, and, ultimately, a society whose productivity cannot compete on the international scene. I.e. : Decline.
The same tandem interaction can be seen between politicians and voters. Voters elect politicians who, in turn, shape culture and social capital through their policies. People in Russia WANTED communism, established it, and then communism steered their culture even more towards dependency (something they still carry, but because of their still recent sour memories of red coercive collectivism, they think they will find salvation in black coercive collectivism instead — while their western useful-idiot counterparts have gravitated towards green coercive collectivism).
All this points to the fact that there is a very non-linear tipping point where social capital erodes, and a virtuous cycle quickly becomes a vicious cycle of decline. This is, I’m afraid, the tipping point we saw when American voters in 2008, plagued by the problems brought upon by an accumulation of coercive collectivism, elected an administration with even more coercive collectivist aspirations. I think that was the year where the vicious cycle closed. The results of the current election do not seem to change this general trajectory much.
What voters do not seem to understand is that the difference between virtuous and vicious cycle depends on very narrow margins, just like success at a company against worldwide competitors also depends on very narrow margins.
If I could quantify it, I’d say that the tipping point is crossed when your country’s effort-reward curve drops below the world average. Then, your growth rate drops below the world average and you are toast. You decline – as it is only a matter of time before the growth deficit compounds your standard of living down towards the world average.
But… at a more fundamental level,…
…coercive collectivism is baked in our human genes. Why? Because it was actually beneficial during most of our human very-slow-growth evolution. It was more beneficial for individuals to follow the narrow established and very slow evolving practices, shaped through the ages, rather than launch into new random, and most likely detrimental, endeavors. Not so in a modern world where 4% growth blesses every human with significant standard of living improvements throughout his/her lifetime.
But we cannot get rid of your genes. They do evolve — and will evolve — but very-very slowly. Religion comes in to fill the void and correct the great biological inertia of genetic adaptation. Religion can evolve in a few decades, as opposed to genetic evolution which takes thousands of years. Religion can persuade a selfish libertarian to be more compassionate (hence to give without impacting his motivation) and can also convince a socialist to refrain from attempting to live by milking the labor of a more exceptional or more motivated minority. Religion, or at least the right religion, works both ends to help the unfortunate portion of the less well off, without eroding social capital. And, at the societal level, small advantages, whether religious or other, quickly compound into huge prosperity divergences (and will continue to do so with increasing speed as everything human continues to accelerate going forward). As you can probably tell, I’m not personally religious.
In any case, this genetic baggage is all about to change again, as humanity will soon take control of its own genetic destiny. Whether you like it or not (I’m personally very excited about it) it will happen. The genie cannot be kept in the bottle. In the not so distant future, you will be able to genetically intervene in the development of your descendants, perhaps first at the embryonic level (the first cell, like in-vitro fertilization) and turn off the telomere shortening mechanism that makes them age and die (*). When it happens, I dare you to not take advantage of it. You can say “yes my children could have a three century life span through this minor modification, but I won’t be greedy and thus I am irreversibly choosing to have them die at 70,80,90… whatever”. I dare you indeed.
When one calculates that even at 3% world growth (current trendline is 4%) our descendants in the next century will be x19 times (yes, that is 1900%) wealthier than we are today, this will also encompass disruptive breakthrough fantastical changes like the one I just described. It HAS to involve such fantastic surprises, otherwise how will the x19 improvement materialize? The x19 prosperity multiplier is a proxy not only for economic wealth but also scientific and technological; of fantastic and unimaginable to us proportions.
I know that at this point many will label me a childish dreamer. But I’m no different than someone in 1880 who claims that someday people will fly, and refuses to seriously discuss the problems of the time (like the predicted upcoming shortage of salt) in the popular talk show of the times. But who called it right in the end? The optimist who thought that humans would fly, or the pessimists who thought humanity would run out of salt (or communications due to telegraph poles becoming extinct from people burning trees to heat their homes)?
Keep this post. In 100 years (or perhaps sooner) we will see who called it right. The answer will come a lot faster than Al Gore’s next 1C in world temperature rise.
Meanwhile, for the pathetic, defeatist, and declining electorates of moist western democracies: “A redistribution dollar today is worth five perpetually compounding growth dollars in the future”. So, believe in HopNChange and perpetuate the decline of western world democracies down towards a rising world average. Don’t need to stay at the top of the prosperity rankings? When the most advanced and prosperous societies in the world will start having access to processes that let them live two- three centuries, I dare you to not be greedy and not want it.
(*) It may turn out to be something other than the telomere mechanism. It is virtually impossible for me to predict exactly in the ignorance of our comparatively primitive world. But it will happen. If not that, other fantastical changes will happen, changes I’m no better able to predict than a person in 1880 could predict today. But happen they will, and fantastic they will be.
Please excuse the typos: attitudes, Capital, Social, quickly, forget, are some of the incorrectly misspelled words.
Yes there is Social Capital. That is only one half of the equasion. The other half is Social Deficit. Social Capital is the act of creative capitalism, and the attituteds , and WORK of those creative individuals, insitutions and businesses who create that wealth. Social Deficit is possible only as the creation of the GOVERNMENT, which takes from Social Caital in the guise of “Social Justice, Social Fairness, Solcial Equality and whatever other invented phrases that the Communists-Socialists-Democrats constantly invent or reinvent to create the culture of “victimhood” and to justify the redistribution of wealth. How qickly we forgent. The words of George Santayana are so very relevant here. Those who cannot remember the past are condemned to repeat it. These are the SAME or similar Communist-Socialst-Democrat slogans identified by Frederic Hayek in his classical dissertation, “The Road to Serfdom,” written in the last century. To paraphrase Ronald Reagan: Government IS the problem. The Communists-Socialists-Democrats are constantly trying to reinvent history with their discredited slogans to convince us that Capitalism is evils and that Socialism is good. It is clear to note, that worldwide, socialism has become a massive and unsustainable failure. It cannot exist without the increasing and unsustainsble burden of taxation upon the people. Socialism is a FAILED system of governance. Socialism = slavery and serfdom. Capitalism = Freedom.
This old TED talk is sort of in line with this post- regarding the shift from centrally planned economies to more individual freedom:
I found it interesting. Regardless of culture, statism is awful and capitalism is good.
Mr. Dan, I have seen recently that Japan is now officially in a recession and I know its economy has been in the doldrums for two decades. What, exactly, is the cause of Japan’s problems? And is that our fate as well? Thanks!