It’s not very often that I applaud research from the International Monetary Fund.
That international bureaucracy has a bad track record of pushing for tax hikes and other policies to augment the size and power of government (which shouldn’t surprise us since the IMF’s lavishly compensated bureaucrats owe their sinecures to government and it wouldn’t make sense for them to bite the hands that feed them).
But every so often a blind squirrel finds an acorn. And that’s a good analogy to keep in mind as we review a new IMF report on the efficacy of “expenditure rules.”
The study is very neutral in its language. It describes expenditure rules and then looks at their impact. But the conclusions, at least for those of us who want to constrain government, show that these policies are very valuable.
In effect, this study confirms the desirability of my Golden Rule! Which is not why I expect from IMF research, to put it mildly.
Here are some excerpts from the IMF’s new Working Paper on expenditure rules.
In practice, expenditure rules typically take the form of a cap on nominal or real spending growth over the medium term (Figure 1). Expenditure rules are currently in place in 23 countries (11 in advanced and 12 in emerging economies).
Such rules vary, of course, is their scope and effectiveness.
Many of them apply only to parts of the budget. In some cases, governments don’t follow through on their commitments. And in other cases, the rules only apply for a few years.
Out of the 31 expenditure rules that have been introduced since 1985, 10 have already been abandoned either because the country
has never complied with the rule or because fiscal consolidation was so successful that the government did not want to be restricted by the rule in good economic times. … In six of the 10 cases, the country did not comply with the rule in the year before giving it up. …In some countries, there was the perception that expenditure rules fulfilled their purpose. Following successful consolidations in Belgium, Canada, and the United States in the 1990s, these countries did not see the need to follow their national expenditure rules anymore.
But even though expenditure limits are less than perfect, they’re still effective – in part because they correctly put the focus on the disease of government spending rather than symptom of red ink.
Countries have complied with expenditure rules for more than two-third of the time. …expenditure rules have a better compliance record than budget balance and debt rules. …The higher compliance rate with expenditure rules is consistent with the fact that these rules are easy to monitor and that they immediately map into an enforceable mechanism—the annual budget itself. Besides, expenditure rules are most directly connected to instruments that the policymakers effectively control. By contrast, the budget balance, and even more so public debt, is more exposed to shocks, both positive and negative, out of the government’s control.
One of the main advantages of a spending cap is that politicians can’t go on a spending binge when the economy is growing and generating a lot of tax revenue.
One of the desirable features of expenditure rules compared to other rules is that they are not only binding in bad but also in good economic times. The compliance rate in good economic times, defined as years with a negative change in the output gap, is at 72 percent almost the same as in bad economic times at 68 percent. In contrast to other fiscal rules, countries also have incentives to break an expenditure rule in periods of high economic growth with increasing spending pressures. … two design features are in particular associated with higher compliance rates. …compliance is higher if the government directly controls the expenditure target. …Specific ceilings have the best performance record.
And the most important result is that expenditure limits are associated with a lower burden of government spending.
The results illustrate that countries with expenditure rules, in addition to other rules, exhibit on average higher primary balances (Table 2). Similarly, countries with expenditure rules also exhibit lower primary spending. …The data provide some evidence of possible implications for government size and efficiency. Event studies illustrate that the introduction of expenditure rules is indeed followed by smaller governments both in advanced and emerging countries (Figure 11a).
Here’s the relevant chart from the study.
And it’s also worth noting that expenditure rules lead to greater efficiency in spending.
…the public investment efficiency index of DablaNorris and others (2012) is higher in countries that do have expenditure rules in place compared to those that do not (Figure 11b). This could be due to investment projects being prioritized more carefully relative to the case where there is no binding constraint on spending
Needless to say, these results confirm the research from the European Central Bank showing that nations with smaller public sectors are more efficient and competent, with Singapore being a very powerful example.
One rather puzzling aspect of the IMF report is that there was virtually no mention of Switzerland’s spending cap, which is a role model of success.
Perhaps the researchers got confused because the policy is called a “debt brake,” but the practical effect of the Swiss rule is that there are annual expenditures limits.
So to augment the IMF analysis, here are some excerpts from a report prepared by the Swiss Federal Finance Administration.
The Swiss “debt brake” or “debt containment rule”…combines the stabilizing properties of an expenditure rule (because of the cyclical adjustment) with the effective debt-controlling properties of a balanced budget rule. …The amount of annual federal government expenditures has a cap, which is calculated as a function of revenues and the position of the economy in the business cycle. It is thus aimed at keeping total federal government expenditures relatively independent of cyclical variations.
Here’s a chart from the report.
And here are some of the real-world results.
The debt-to-GDP ratio of the Swiss federal Government has decreased since the implementation of the debt brake in 2003. …In the past, economic booms tended to contribute to an increase in spending. …This has not been the case since the implementation of the fiscal rule, and budget surpluses have become commonplace. … The introduction of the debt brake has changed the budget process in such a way that the target for expenditures is defined at the beginning of the process, which must not exceed the ceiling provided by the fiscal rule. It has thus become a top-down process.
The most important part of this excerpt is that the debt brake prevented big spending increases during the “boom” years when the economy was generating lots of revenue.
In effect, the grey-colored area of the graph isn’t just an “ideal representation.” It actually happened in the real world.
Though the most important and beneficial real-world consequence, which I shared back in 2013, is that the burden of government spending has declined relative to the economy’s productive sector.
This is a big reason why Switzerland is in such strong shape compared to most of its European neighbors.
And such a policy in the United States would have prevented the trillion-dollar deficits of Obama’s first term.
By the way, if you want to know why deficit numbers have been lower in recent years, it’s because we actually have been following my Golden Rule for a few years.
So maybe it’s time to add the United States to this list of nations that have made progress with spending restraint.
But the real issue, as noted in the IMF research, is sustainability. Yes, it’s good to have a few years of spending discipline, but the real key is some sort of permanent spending cap.
Which is why advocates of fiscal responsibility should focus on expenditure limits rather than balanced budget requirements.
[…] what’s more surprising are that pro-spending cap studies from the International Monetary Fund (here and here), the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (here and here) and the […]
[…] what’s more surprising are that pro-spending cap studies from the International Monetary Fund (here and here), the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (here and here) and the […]
[…] more surprising are that pro-spending cap studies from the International Monetary Fund (here and here), the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (here and here) and the […]
[…] to a rule that is much easier to enforce(increasing spending by, say, 2 percent every year is very straightforward compared to the wild swings in spending that occur with a balanced budget […]
[…] to a rule that is much easier to enforce (increasing spending by, say, 2 percent every year is very straightforward compared to the wild swings in spending that occur with a balanced budget […]
[…] Ironically, economists at the IMF have written in favor of spending caps on multiple occasions. Too bad the political hacks in charge of the bureaucracy don’t pay […]
[…] also written about that research, citing studies by the International Monetary Fund (here and here), the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (here and here) and the […]
[…] also written about that research, citing studies by the International Monetary Fund (here and here), the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (here and here) and the […]
[…] also written about that research, citing studies by the International Monetary Fund (here and here), the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (here and here) and the […]
[…] contrast, the International Monetary Fund (twice!), the European Central Bank, and the Organization for Economic Cooperation and […]
[…] poisonous advice. Second, I feel sorry for the economists and other professionals at the IMF (who often produce high–quality research). They must wince with embarrassment every time garbage […]
[…] caps have such a good track record that even left-leaning international bureaucracies like the International Monetary Fund and the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development have acknowledged that they are the […]
[…] good research. In the past, I’ve highlight some very good IMF studies on topics such as spending caps, the size of government, taxes and business vitality, fiscal decentralization, the Laffer Curve, […]
[…] Spending caps work so well that even left-leaning international bureaucracies such as the OECD and IMF have acknowledged that they are the only effective fiscal […]
[…] caps are the only fiscal rules that have a strong track record, even confirmed by research from the International Monetary Fund and Organization for Economic Cooperation and […]
[…] the IMF and OECD agree with me that this is a big reason why anti-deficit rules don’t […]
[…] I hope the political decision makers at the IMF read this study (as well as prior IMF studies on the efficacy of spending caps) and no longer will agitate for tax increases on nations that get […]
[…] it’s not just me saying this. Even left-leaning international bureaucracies such as the International Monetary Fund (twice), the European Central Bank, and the Organization for Economic Cooperation and […]
[…] it’s not just me saying this. Even left-leaning international bureaucracies such as the International Monetary Fund (twice), the European Central Bank, and the Organization for Economic Cooperation and […]
[…] who work for the IMF and that they occasionally are allowed to produce good research. I’ve favorably cited the bureaucracy’s work on spending caps, for […]
[…] who work for the IMF and that they occasionally are allowed to produce good research. I’ve favorably cited the bureaucracy’s work on spending caps, for […]
[…] International Bureaucracies Agree – Remarkably, the International Monetary Fund (twice!), the European Central Bank, and the Organization for Economic Cooperation and […]
[…] reconnaissons que le FMI produit parfois de bonnes analyses. Les économistes de cette bureaucratie ont conclu (à deux reprises !) que les plafonds de dépenses constituent la règle fiscale la plus efficace. […]
[…] to acknowledge that we sometimes get good analysis from the IMF. Economists from that bureaucracy have concluded (two times!) that spending caps are the most effective fiscal rule. They also made some good […]
[…] will acknowledge occasional good research (on taxation, government spending, financial regulation, spending caps, etc), but there’s no question that the net impact of the IMF is […]
[…] the economists at the IMF have produced research on the benefits of smaller government and spending caps. But the political leadership at the IMF routinely ignores that sensible research and instead has a […]
[…] but misguided, I’m going to classify my columns on spending caps as Part Va, Part Vb, Part Vc, Part Vd, Part Ve, Part Vf, Part Vg, Part Vh, Part Vi, and Part Vj of my fiscal-fights-with-friends […]
[…] And research from the International Monetary Fund echoes this argument. […]
[…] but the professional economists at the organization have concluded in two separate studies (see here and here) that expenditure limits produce good […]
[…] experts. And we even see that normally left-leaning international bureaucracies such as theOECD and IMF acknowledge that spending caps are the only effective fiscal rule. So if Ulysses can bind himself […]
[…] produces sloppy and dishonest research, every so often the professional economists on the staff slip something useful past the political types. Though my all-time-favorite bit of IMF research was the study that […]
[…] bottom line is similar. I’m a huge fan of spending caps (which have a much better track record than balanced budget […]
[…] lower tax burdens (even if the economists working for these organizations sometimes produce very good research on fiscal […]
[…] already highlighted how the International Monetary Fund (twice!), the European Central Bank, and the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development […]
[…] IMF economists have concluded (two times!) that spending caps are the most effective fiscal rule, I really wonder whether the […]
[…] contrast, you do get some worthwhile research from the career economists (on issues such as spending caps, fiscal decentralization, and the Laffer […]
[…] already highlighted how both the International Monetary Fund (twice!) and the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development have acknowledged that […]
[…] And we even see that normally left-leaning international bureaucracies such as the OECD and IMF acknowledge that spending caps are the only effective fiscal […]
[…] experts. And we even see that normally left-leaning international bureaucracies such as the OECDand IMF acknowledge that spending caps are the only effective fiscal […]
[…] And we even see that normally left-leaning international bureaucracies such as the OECD and IMF acknowledge that spending caps are the only effective fiscal […]
[…] By the way, Kevin mentioned in his testimony that even the IMF has identified spending caps as the only effective fiscal rule. […]
[…] This is why the real solution is to have some sort of enforceable cap on government spending. That approach has worked well in jurisdictions such as Switzerland, Hong Kong, and Colorado. And even research from the IMF (a bureaucracy that shares CRFB’s misplaced fixation on debt) has concluded that expenditure limits are the only effective fiscal rules. […]
[…] even the crowd at the IMF has felt compelled to admit spending caps are the only effective fiscal […]
[…] even the IMF agrees that spending caps are the only feasible […]
[…] in March, I shared a remarkable study from the International Monetary Fundwhich explained that spending caps are the only truly effective way to achieve good fiscal […]
[…] in March, I shared a remarkable study from the International Monetary Fund which explained that spending caps are the only truly effective way to achieve good fiscal […]
[…] even the International Monetary Fund now acknowledges that spending caps are the only effective fiscal […]
[…] amazingly, even the International Monetary Fund agrees that spending caps are the most effective strategy for good fiscal […]
John:
Thanks for the book suggestions:
I should be getting “Balance” shortly. The library didn’t have “Steering Clear”, but it did have two other Peter Peterson books that looked interesting.
Nick:
I clicked on your link and got only pictures, no sound, no verbiage to tell me what it was about.
Dick:
While I agree with most of what you say, it is possible for government to spend money in ways that grow the economy. The problem is that they don’t have a profit motive to guide them to the projects most likely to be beneficial. The second problem is that they ignore or are missing pricing information that might tell them when to stop investing.
On the downside, since government spending is normally undertaken for special interest groups that could not get their funding in the private sector, it is far less likely that investments will be successful for other than that specific group.
I have to take sides with Mr. Dan over John Knubel. Government spending is, by definition, ALWAYS a drag on the total economy. Government produces nothing; therefore, it can spend only from the net production of the private sector. That subtracts from what the private sector has available for growth and thus lowers the national growth rate. The bigger the government, the bigger the drag.
By Mr. Knubel’s reasoning a balanced budget where total government spending is 70% of the economy is better than an unbalanced budget where total government spending is 20% of the economy. No. It is the SIZE of government itself and the net impact to, as Zorba always points out, the compounded growth of the economy that is the long-term problem.
In the course of 2 centuries, this nation went from a vast wilderness to the most productive nation on the planet almost solely because its citizens were free from an overbearing government. And we have managed to maintain the highest standard of living in the world only because the governments of other nations are as big and as intrusive as ours has become.
When the day comes that a plausible path exists for 38 states to ratify a spending limit, the Compact for America team will be there. Until then, nothing is more powerful AND plausible if you want to stop fiscal insanity than the federal Balanced Budget Amendment we are advancing. Check it out http://www.CompactforAmerica.org
John:
A balanced budget approach is flawed. Bureaucrats and politicians operate to improve their personal power base, which means more spending. The attempt to balance their spending desires with revenues to fund them will always lead to demands for more tax revenues.
Higher tax rates and a wider variety of tax sources do not necessarily lead to higher tax revenues, given Laffer effects and the secondary effect of higher tax rates leading to higher prices and therefore a slowing economy. Therefore, the only truly effective way to get close to a balanced budget is to bring down spending.
I would propose that the best way to contain spending is not to write it into law, since our legislators can change/ignore laws; but instead create a bonus system for legislators. For example, provide legislators with a bonus around 2x salary that they receive if spending is less than a certain percentage of GDP, on an all or nothing basis. This does two things: It obviously puts a cap on spending. Second, it encourages efforts to increase GDP growth, such as reducing regulations and fixing the tax code.
One final note: Debt is not an evil, but rather just a form of financing. If debt is growing slower than the economy, all is well. We have been using debt to finance current consumption, which does nothing to promote future growth. If debt financing is limited to capital improvements, that’s an acceptable financing technique.
[…] The debt-to-GDP ratio of the Swiss federal Government has decreased since the implementation of the WAIT, THERE’S MORE… […]
Dan, I really appreciate your research and will use it in my new book America in Denial. But I so grieve the fact that you seem to posture yourself against a balanced budget approach. Consider the following. Both Mr Glenn Hubbard in his book “Balance” ;and the latest Steering Clear from Pete Peterson acknowledge the need to give Congress some flexibility in deciding what size government we have.
That after all is their constitutional role.
And the reason we’re running up so much debt is that today we have people on the right trying to reduce government at the same time people on the left are maintaining it or trying to increase it and the result is gridlock and a country threatening explosion of debt. I know as a libertarian the Cato is dead set against any increase and would like to tear down government but can’t we see how far that’s gotten us to date. We are now running major deficits and the only way to get a spending cap, based on my historical observation is to create some sort of a balanced budget amendment approach. Thanks for your work and for sending this out but I really think you are in jeopardy of sacrificing the good while trying to get the best and as the British say, throwing the baby out with the bathwater. Please don’t posture yourself as being against the balanced budget approved that’s the only way we can get spending caps.
Even a blind squirrel occasionally finds an acorn.
[…] By Dan Mitchell […]