The International Monetary Fund is a left-leaning bureaucracy that was set up to monitor the fixed-exchange-rate monetary system created after World War II.
Unsurprisingly, when that system broke down and the world shifted to floating exchange rates, the IMF didn’t go away. Instead, it created a new role for itself as self-styled guardian of economic stability.
Which is a bit of a joke since the international bureaucracy is most infamous for its relentless advocacy of higher taxes in economically stressed nations. So much so that I’ve labeled the IMF the Dr. Kevorkian of the world economy.
Or if that reference is a bit outdated for younger readers, let’s just say the IMF is the dumpster fire of international economics. Heck, if I was in Beijing, I would consider the bureaucracy’s recommendations for China an act of war.
To get an idea of the IMF’s ideological bias, let’s review it’s new report designed to discredit economic liberty (a.k.a., “neoliberalism” in the European sense or “classical liberalism” to Americans).
Here’s their definition.
The neoliberal agenda—a label used more by critics than by the architects of the policies— rests on two main planks. The first is increased competition—achieved through deregulation and the opening up of domestic markets, including financial markets, to foreign competition. The second is a smaller role for the state, achieved through privatization and limits on the ability of governments to run fiscal deficits and accumulate debt.
The authors describe the first plank accurately, but they mischaracterize the second plank.
At the risk of nitpicking, I would say “neoliberals” such as myself are much more direct than they imply. We want to achieve “a smaller role for the state” by reducing the burden of government spending.
Sure, we want to privatize government-controlled assets, but that’s mostly for reasons of economic efficiency rather than budgetary savings. And because we care about what actually works, we’re fans of spending caps rather than balanced budget rules.
But let’s set all that aside and get back to the report.
The IMF authors point out that governments have been moving in the right direction in recent decades.
There has been a strong and widespread global trend toward neoliberalism since the 1980s.
That sounds like good news.
And the report even includes a couple of graphs to show the trend toward free markets and limited government.
And the bureaucrats even concede that free markets and small government generate some good results.
There is much to cheer in the neoliberal agenda. The expansion of global trade has rescued millions from abject poverty. Foreign direct investment has often been a way to transfer technology and know-how to developing economies. Privatization of state-owned enterprises has in many instances led to more efficient provision of services and lowered the fiscal burden on governments.
But then the authors get to their real point. They don’t like unfettered capital flows and they don’t like so-called austerity.
However, there are aspects of the neoliberal agenda that have not delivered as expected. …removing restrictions on the movement of capital across a country’s borders (so-called capital account liberalization); and fiscal consolidation, sometimes called “austerity,” which is shorthand for policies to reduce fiscal deficits and debt levels.
Looking at these two aspects of neoliberalism, the IMF proposes “three disquieting conclusions.”
I’m much more worried about stagnation and poverty than I am about inequality, so part of the IMF’s analysis can be dismissed.
Indeed, based on the sloppiness of previous IMF work on inequality, one might be tempted to dismiss the entire report.
But let’s look at whether the authors have a point. Are there negative economic consequences for nations that allow open capital flows and/or impose budgetary restraint?
They argue that passive financial flows (indirect investment) can be destabilizing.
Some capital inflows, such as foreign direct investment—which may include a transfer of technology or human capital—do seem to boost long-term growth. But the impact of other flows—such as portfolio investment and banking and especially hot, or speculative, debt inflows—seem neither to boost growth nor allow the country to better share risks with its trading partners… Although growth benefits are uncertain, costs in terms of increased economic volatility and crisis frequency seem more evident. Since 1980, there have been about 150 episodes of surges in capital inflows in more than 50 emerging market economies…about 20 percent of the time, these episodes end in a financial crisis, and many of these crises are associated with large output declines… In addition to raising the odds of a crash, financial openness has distributional effects, appreciably raising inequality. …there is increased acceptance of controls to limit short-term debt flows that are viewed as likely to lead to—or compound—a financial crisis. While not the only tool available—exchange rate and financial policies can also help—capital controls are a viable, and sometimes the only, option when the source of an unsustainable credit boom is direct borrowing from abroad.
I certainly agree that there have been various crises in different nations, but I’m wondering whether the IMF is focusing on the symptoms rather than the underlying diseases.
What happened in the various nations, for instance, to trigger sudden capital flight? That seems to be a much more important question.
In some cases, such as Greece, the problem obviously isn’t capital flight. It’s the reckless spending by Greek politicians that created a fiscal crisis.
In other cases, such as Estonia, there was a bubble because of an overheated property market, and there’s no question the economy took a hit when that bubble popped.
But there’s a very strong case that Estonia’s open economy has generated plenty of strong growth over the years to compensate for that blip.
And it’s worth noting that criticisms of Estonia’s market-oriented policies often are based on grotesque inaccuracies, as was the case when Paul Krugman tried to blame the 2008 recession on spending cuts that occurred in 2009.
So I’m very skeptical of the IMF’s claim that capital controls are warranted. That’s the type of policy designed to insulate governments from the consequences of bad policy.
Now let’s shift to the fiscal policy issue. The IMF report correctly states that “Curbing the size of the state is another aspect of the neoliberal agenda.”
But the authors make a big (perhaps deliberate) mistake by then blaming neoliberals for adverse consequences associated with the “austerity” imposed by various governments.
Austerity policies not only generate substantial welfare costs due to supply-side channels, they also hurt demand—and thus worsen employment and unemployment. …in practice, episodes of fiscal consolidation have been followed, on average, by drops rather than by expansions in output. On average, a consolidation of 1 percent of GDP increases the long-term unemployment rate by 0.6 percentage point.
The problem with this analysis is that it doesn’t differentiate between tax increases and spending cuts.
And since much of the “austerity” is the former variety rather than the latter, especially in Europe, it borders on malicious for the IMF to blame neoliberals (who want less spending) for the economic consequences of IMF-endorsed policies (mostly higher taxes).
Especially since research from the European Central Bank and International Monetary Fund (!) show that spending restraint is the pro-growth way of dealing with a fiscal crisis.
Let’s now look at what the IMF authors suggest for future policy. More taxes and spending!
…policymakers should be more open to redistribution than they are. …And fiscal consolidation strategies—when they are needed—could be designed to minimize the adverse impact on low-income groups. But in some cases, the untoward distributional consequences will have to be remedied after they occur by using taxes and government spending to redistribute income. Fortunately, the fear that such policies will themselves necessarily hurt growth is unfounded.
Wow, the last couple of sentences are remarkable. The bureaucrats want readers to believe that a bigger fiscal burden of government won’t have any adverse consequences.
That’s a spectacular level of anti-empiricism. I guess they want us to believe that nations such as France are economically stronger economy than places such as Hong Kong.
Wow.
Last but not least, here’s a final excerpt that’s worth sharing just because of these two sentences.
IMF Managing Director Christine Lagarde said the institution believed that the U.S. Congress was right to raise the country’s debt ceiling “because the point is not to contract the economy by slashing spending brutally now as recovery is picking up.” …Policymakers, and institutions like the IMF that advise them, must be guided not by faith, but by evidence of what has worked.
We’re supposed to believe the IMF is guided by evidence when the chief bureaucrat relies on Keynesian theory to make a dishonest argument. I wish that “slashing spending” was one of the options on the table when the debt limit was raised, but the fight was at the margins over how rapidly the burden of spending should climb.
But if Lagarde can make that argument with a straight face, I guess she deserves her massive tax-free compensation package.
P.S. Since IMF economists have concluded (two times!) that spending caps are the most effective fiscal rule, I really wonder whether the authors of the above study were being deliberately dishonest when they blamed advocates of lower spending for the negative impact of higher taxes.
P.P.S. I was greatly amused in 2014 when the IMF took two diametrically opposed positions on infrastructure spending in a three-month period.
P.P.P.S. The one silver lining to the dark cloud of the IMF is that the bureaucrats inadvertently generated some very powerful evidence against the VAT.
P.P.P.S. Let’s close with something positive. IMF researchers last year found that decentralized government works better.
[…] the bureaucracy highlights second-rate analysis in pursuit of bad […]
[…] admire the IMF. The bureaucracy’s rationale for existence (dealing with fixed exchange rates) disappeared decades ago, yet the IMF managed to reinvent itself and is now bigger and more bloated than […]
[…] And when you realize who controls the purse strings, it’s no surprise to learn that the bureaucracy is a persistent advocate of higher tax burdens and bigger government. Especially when the IMF’s politicized and leftist (and tax-free) leadership dictates the organization’s agenda. […]
[…] And when you realize who controls the purse strings, it’s no surprise to learn that the bureaucracy is a persistent advocate of higher tax burdens and bigger government. Especially when the IMF’s politicized and leftist (and tax-free) leadership dictates the organization’s agenda. […]
[…] Si le FMI se contentait de perdre beaucoup d’argent pour produire des prévisions inexactes1, je ne serais pas trop contrarié. Après tout, les économistes semblent avoir pour spécialité de se tromper sur l’avenir. Mon problème est que le FMI pousse à l’adoption de mauvaises politiques. […]
[…] After all, economists seemingly specialize in getting the future wrong. My problem is that the IMF pushes bad policy. […]
[…] While the IMF often produces sloppy and dishonest research, every so often the professional economists on the staff slip something useful past the […]
[…] object to the way these international bureaucracies are cheerleaders for bigger government and higher tax burdens. Even though they ostensibly exist to promote greater levels of […]
[…] The IMF and OECD disgracefully took part in “Project Fear” by concocting hysterical predictions of […]
[…] The IMF and OECD disgracefully took part in “Project Fear” by concocting hysterical predictions […]
[…] probably never did something as duplicitous as advising governments to boost tax burdens and then publishing a report to say that the subsequent economic damage was evidence against the free-market […]
[…] are even more laughable. The IMF is a left-wing organization with a dismal track record of sloppy and disingenuous output. And the OECD also is infamous for a statist perspective and dishonest data […]
The arguments against income inequality don’t make sense.
With extreme poverty, a case can be made that the underfed and under-educated cannot be productive resources, until they are brought up to some minimal standard; but this is an extreme situation.
Redistribution by government of a fixed pie should have no immediate effect. One group benefits, while the other loses. The is a residual effect, in that the wealthy invest a larger portion in future growth verses consumables, so redistribution from the wealthy to the poor results is slower future growth.
In a growing economy, inequality will necessarily grow. Growth does not occur universally, but in discrete sectors, from productivity improvements or entrepreneurial activity. The sectors producing the highest growth benefit the most while those that lag may still receive ancillary benefits but benefit less. There will also be those whose jobs or businesses are disrupted by growth, but in a growing economy people and assets will soon be reallocated.
Redistribution of some of the benefits of growth may be appropriate as a safety-net, to lessen the necessary disruption that comes with growth. However, if an attempt is made to reallocate completely the benefits of growth, all incentives for growth disappear, as do the disincentives for poor asset allocation.
There’s an enormous yet little appreciated difference between austerity for tax-payers and austerity for the government. Yet the failure to differentiate is key to continued government failure all over the globe.
see http://www.lifestrategies.net/austerity