Back in 2016, I shared an image that showed how the welfare state punishes both the poor and rich.
Rich people are hurt for the obvious reason. They get hit with the highest statutory tax rates, and also bear the brunt of the double taxation (the extra layers of tax on saving and investment resulting from capital gains taxes, double taxes on dividends, death taxes, etc).
But I also pointed out that the poor are penalized because they get trapped in dependency.
In large part, this is because they face bad incentives when they work and try to become self sufficient. Not only do they get hit by federal and state taxes, but they also can lose access to various redistribution programs. And the combination of those two factors can produce very high implicit marginal tax rates.
I cited an astounding example of this phenomenon in 2012, showing that a single mother in Pennsylvania would be better off earning $29,000 rather than $57,000. In other words, her implicit marginal tax rate on an extra $28,000 would be 100 percent (thus fulfilling FDR’s odious dream, albeit against a different set of victims).
How pervasive is this problem?
A new study published by the National Bureau of Economic Research gives us the answer. Authored by David Altig, Alan J. Auerbach, Laurence J. Kotlikoff, Elias Ilin, and Victor Ye, it estimates implicit marginal tax rates for various segments of the population.
A plethora of federal and state tax and benefit policies jointly determine Americans’ incentives to work. …complex and often arcane provisions that condition tax payments and benefit receipts on labor income, asset income, total income, and the level of assets.
…The myriad features of our fiscal system raise this paper’s central questions: What are the typical levels of marginal net tax rates facing Americans of different ages and resource levels, taking the entire federal and state fiscal system into account? …How much does one’s choice of the state in which to live impact one’s incentive to work? …We address these questions by running 2016 Survey-of-Consumer-Finances (SCF) data through The Fiscal Analyzer (TFA).
The five economists discovered that lower-income people are often hit by very high marginal tax rates on work (τL).
Our main findings, which focus on the fiscal consequences of SCF household heads earning $1,000 more in our base year – 2018, are striking. One in four low-wage workers face lifetime marginal net tax rates above 70 percent, effectively locking them into poverty. Over half face remaining lifetime marginal net tax rates above 45 percent. …marginal net lifetime tax rates are generally higher for those in the lowest quintile than for those in the middle three quintiles… The potential poverty trap arising under our fiscal system is highlighted by the 75th τL-percentile values for the bottom quintiles. Moving from the youngest to the oldest cohorts, these values are 67.4 percent, 75.9 percent, 69.3 percent, 76.5 percent, 74.4 percent, and 73.9 percent. Hence, one in four of our poorest households, regardless of age, make between two and three times as much for the government than they make for themselves in earning an extra $1,000.
This graph from the study shows how poor people can even face marginal tax rates of more than 100 percent (which I’ve highlighted in red). The vertical axis is the tax rate and the horizontal axis is household prosperity.
Subjecting poor people to very high implicit tax rates is horrible economic policy, just like it’s horrible policy to hit any other group of people with high marginal tax rates.
Simply stated, when people are punished for engaging in productive economic behavior, they respond by reducing their work, their saving, their investment, and their entrepreneurship.
Interestingly, some states are better (or less worse) than others.
One’s choice of state in which to live can dramatically affect marginal net tax rates. Across all cohorts, the typical bottom-quintile household can lower its remaining lifetime marginal net tax rate by 99.7 percentage points by switching states! …The typical household can raise its total remaining lifetime spending by 8.1 percent by moving from a high-tax to a low-tax state, holding its human wealth, housing expenses, and other characteristics fixed. …To illustrate how τL varies from state to state, we calculate the median τL for households in the 30-39 age cohort in the lowest resource quintile in each state. …Figure 11 shows the cross-state variation in median lifetime marginal tax rates. …median rates varies between a low of 38.8 percent in South Carolina and a high of 55.0 percent in Connecticut. Clearly, where people live can matter a lot for their incentives to work.
Here’s a map showing the marginal tax rate on people in the bottom 20 percent. The obvious takeaway is that you don’t want to be a poor person in Connecticut, Minnesota, or Illinois.
For what it’s worth, tax rates are still too high in the best states (South Carolina, Texas, Indiana, and South Dakota).
The bottom line is that the welfare state is bad news for both taxpayers and recipients. All of which may help to explain why the poverty rate stopped falling once the government declared a “War on Poverty.”
[…] And a decision to work only a small amount may be a result of high implicit marginal tax rates that are embedded in redistribution programs. […]
[…] And a decision to work only a small amount may be a result of high implicit marginal tax rates that are embedded in redistribution programs. […]
[…] And a decision to work only a small amount may be a result of high implicit marginal tax rates that are embedded in redistribution programs. […]
[…] stated, why work harder or work more when an additional dollar of income only leads to a net benefit of 10 cents or 20 cents? Or why work harder or work more when you can actually wind up being worse […]
[…] If you want more evidence, check out Chart 7 from this columnand Figure 8 from this column. […]
[…] If you want more evidence, check out Chart 7 from this columnand Figure 8 from this column. […]
[…] If you want more evidence, check out Chart 7 from this columnand Figure 8 from this column. […]
[…] stated, why work harder or work more when an additional dollar of income only leads to a net benefit of 10 cents or 20 cents? Or why work harder or work more when you can actually wind up being worse […]
[…] stated, why work harder or work more when an additional dollar of income only leads to a net benefit of 10 cents or 20 cents? Or why work harder or work more when you can actually wind up being worse […]
[…] If you want more evidence, check out Chart 7 from this columnand Figure 8 from this column. […]
[…] If you want more evidence, check out Chart 7 from this column and Figure 8 from this column. […]
[…] The politicians in Washington also believe in very high implicit tax rates on low-income […]
[…] The politicians in Washington also believe in very high implicit tax rates on low-income […]
[…] in the short run, but once they get trapped in the quicksand of government dependency, it’s very difficult to […]
[…] in the short run, but once they get trapped in the quicksand of government dependency, it’s very difficult to […]
[…] notably, there would not be high implicit marginal tax rates on work (a big problem in the current system) since people would get the child allowances regardless of employment […]
[…] notably, there would not be high implicit marginal tax rates on work (a big problem in the current system) since people would get the child allowances regardless of employment […]
[…] week ago, I wrote about how the welfare state creates high implicit marginal tax rates, thus making it difficult […]
[…] – at best – offers the poor a life of dependency (especially when you consider the very high implicit marginal tax rates created by redistribution […]
[…] governments doubtlessly have trapped many poor residents in dependency, especially since there are high implicit marginal tax rates if they seek self-sufficiency and financial […]
[…] P.P.S. In addition to the fiscal burden of entitlement programs, there’s also a major problem in the way these programs discourage work. […]
[…] week ago, I wrote about how the welfare state creates high implicit marginal tax rates, thus making it difficult for […]
[…] week ago, I wrote about how the welfare state creates high implicit marginal tax rates, thus making it difficult for […]
I agree Scott. The reduction in poverty has not come without cost. And the one you point out is one of the worst. Another is the sense of entitlement government programs foster. I appreciate your comment. I also appreciate the fact that on this site people are civil. On so many sites the comments become the equivalent of war zones.
Also don’t forget about the corrosive impact the welfare system has had on marriage. The rise in single-parenthood also parallels the growth in welfare. Hard work and marriage are both key ingredients to upward mobility.
[…] « The Welfare State Penalizes the Poor with High Marginal Tax Rates […]
The poverty rate has fallen since the introduction of government programs. It is now below 5 percent. The often reported 12-13 percent rate is wrong because it fails to take into account government aid. But even that figure is lower than the poverty rate before the Great Society programs began.