The Laffer Curve is a graphical representation of the relationship between tax rates, tax revenue, and taxable income. It is frequently cited by people who want to explain the common-sense notion that punitive tax rates may not generate much additional revenue if people respond in ways that result in less taxable income.
Unfortunately, some people misinterpret the insights of the Laffer Curve. Politicians, for instance, tend to either pretend it doesn’t exist, or they embrace it with excessive zeal and assume all tax cuts “pay for themselves.”
Another problem is that people assume that tax rates should be set at the revenue-maximizing level. I explained back in 2010 that this was wrong. Policy makers should strive to set tax rates at the growth-maximizing level. But since a growth-generating tax is about as common as a unicorn, what this really means is that tax rates should be set to produce enough revenue to finance the growth-maximizing level of government – as illustrated by the Rahn Curve.
That’s the theory of the Laffer Curve. What about the evidence? Where are the revenue-maximizing and growth-maximizing points on the Laffer Curve?
Well, ask five economists and you’ll get nine answers. In part, this is because the answers vary depending on the type of tax, the country, and the time frame. In other words, there is more than one Laffer Curve.
With those caveats in mind, we have some very interesting research produced by two economists, one from the Federal Reserve and the other from the University of Chicago. They have authored a new study that attempts to measure the revenue-maximizing point on the Laffer Curve for the United States and several European nations. Here’s an excerpt from their research.
Figure 6 shows the comparison for the US and EU-14. …Interestingly, the capital tax Laffer curve is affected only very little across countries when human capital is introduced. By contrast, the introduction of human capital has important effects for the labor income tax Laffer curve. Several countries are pushed on the slippery slope sides of their labor tax Laffer curves. …human capital turns labor into a stock variable rather than a flow variable as in the baseline model. Higher labor taxes induce households to work less and to acquire less human capital which in turn leads to lower labor income. Consequently, the labor tax base shrinks much more quickly when labor taxes are raised.
There’s a bit of jargon in this passage, so here are the charts from Figure 6. They look complex, but here are the basic facts to make them easy to understand.
The top chart shows the Laffer Curve for labor taxation, and the bottom chart shows the Laffer Curve for capital taxation. And both charts show different curves for the United States and an average of 14 European nations. Last but not least, the charts show how the Laffer Curves change is you add some real-world assumptions about the role of human capital.
Some people will look at these charts and conclude that there should be higher tax rates. After all, neither the U.S. or E.U. nations are at the revenue-maximizing point (though the paper explains that some European nations actually are on the downward-sloping portion of the curve for capital taxes).
But let’s think about what higher tax rates imply, and we’ll focus on the United States. According to the first chart, labor taxes could be approximately doubled before getting to the downward-sloping portion of the curve. But notice that this means that tax revenues only increase by about 10 percent.
This implies that taxable income would be significantly smaller, presumably because of lower output, but also perhaps due to some combination of tax avoidance and tax evasion.
The key factoid (assuming my late-at-night, back-of-the-envelope calculations are right) is that this study implies that the government would reduce private-sector taxable income by about $20 for every $1 of new tax revenue.
Does that seem like good public policy? Ask yourself what sort of politicians are willing to destroy so much private sector output to get their greedy paws on a bit more revenue.
What about capital taxation? According to the second chart, the government could increase the tax rate from about 40 percent to 70 percent before getting to the revenue-maximizing point.
But that 75 percent increase in the tax rate wouldn’t generate much tax revenue, not even a 10 percent increase. So the question then becomes whether it’s good public policy to destroy a large amount of private output in exchange for a small increase in tax revenue.
Once again, the loss of taxable income to the private sector would dwarf the new revenue for the political class. And the question from above bears repeating. What should we think about politicians willing to make that trade?
And that’s the real lesson of the Laffer Curve. Yes, the politicians usually can collect more revenue, but the concomitant damage to the private sector is very large and people have lower living standards. So that leaves us with one final question. Do we think government spending has a sufficiently high rate-of-return to justify that kind of burden? This Rahn Curve video provides the answer.
[…] is a real debate about the shape of the Laffer Curve and the ideal point on the […]
[…] is a real debate about the shape of the Laffer Curve and the ideal point on the […]
[…] is a real debate about the shape of the Laffer Curve and the ideal point on the […]
[…] Higher tax rates on the rich will shrink the labor supply. […]
[…] Higher tax rates on the rich will shrink the labor supply. […]
[…] Now let’s focus on what shouldn’t happen. As Milton Friedman famously observed in 2001, tax increases are never the solution because politicians will simply spend any additional revenue (and the tax increases also will hurt the economy and cause Laffer-Curve feedback effects). […]
[…] But it’s important to realize that there are actually lots of varieties. […]
[…] Now let’s focus on what shouldn’t happen. As Milton Friedman famously observed in 2001, tax increases are never the solution because politicians will simply spend any additional revenue (and the tax increases also will hurt the economy and cause Laffer-Curve feedback effects). […]
[…] le entrate nel tempo saranno molto al di sotto delle proiezioni. Ed è molto sicuro assumere che il danno economico compenserà facilmente qualsiasi entrata che verrà […]
[…] according to research from economists at the University of Chicago and Federal Reserve, there are some tax increases that […]
[…] according to research from economists at the University of Chicago and Federal Reserve, there are some tax increases that […]
[…] possible the government will collect more revenue, of course, but only at a very high cost to workers, consumers, and […]
[…] that revenues over time will fall far short of projections. And it’s very safe to assume that the economic damage will easily offset any revenues that are […]
[…] revenues over time will fall far short of projections. And it’s very safe to assume that the economic damage will easily offset any revenues that are […]
[…] revenues over time will fall far short of projections. And it’s very safe to assume that the economic damage will easily offset any revenues that are […]
[…] over time will fall far short of projections. And it’s very safe to assume that the economic damage will easily offset any revenues that are […]
[…] revenues over time will fall far short of projections. And it’s very safe to assume that the economic damage will easily offset any revenues that are […]
[…] that revenues over time will fall far short of projections. And it’s very safe to assume that the economic damage will easily offset any revenues that are […]
[…] revenues over time will fall far short of projections. And it’s very safe to assume that the economic damage will easily offset any revenues that are […]
[…] possible the government will collect more revenue, of course, but only at a very high cost to workers, consumers, and […]
[…] possible the government will collect more revenue, of course, but only at a very high cost to workers, consumers, and […]
[…] It’s quite possible that the government will collect more money if Biden’s fiscal plan is enacted, but not as much as politicians think. More important, there will be lots of collateral economic damage. […]
[…] It’s quite possible that the government will collect more money if Biden’s fiscal plan is enacted, but not as much as politicians think. More important, there will be lots of collateral economic damage. […]
[…] Now let’s focus on what shouldn’t happen. As Milton Friedman famously observed in 2001, tax increases are never the solution because politicians will simply spend any additional revenue (and the tax increases also will hurt the economy and cause Laffer-Curve feedback effects). […]
[…] show why this is an important distinction, I specifically cited research from two economists (one from the University of Chicago and one from the Federal Reserve) in hopes […]
[…] ingresos serán menos de lo proyectado por las estimaciones de ingresos estáticos debido a niveles permanentemente más bajos de ingresos […]
[…] of a chance for employment and upward mobility? Would it be class-warfare tax rates that generate large amounts of economic damage compared to potential (if any) […]
[…] a lot of economic damage that occurs as tax rates approach that point, which is why I often cite academic research confirming that one additional dollar of tax revenue is associated with several dollars (or more!) […]
[…] Higher tax rates on the rich will shrink the labor supply. […]
[…] The revenue will be less than projected by static revenue estimates because of permanently lower levels of taxable income. […]
[…] Higher tax rates on the rich will shrink the labor supply. […]
[…] over time, presumably because of the Laffer Curve (further confirming that tax hikes are bad even if they generate some […]
[…] over time, presumably because of the Laffer Curve (further confirming that tax hikes are bad even if they generate some […]
[…] because we should consider the health and vitality of the private sector. Here’s some of what I wrote about some academic research in […]
[…] I cited a study in 2012 showing that a revenue-maximizing tax rate might destroy as much as $20 of private sector output for every $1 collected by government. Only Bernie Sanders […]
[…] As tax rates get closer and closer to the revenue-maximizing point, that means an increasing amount of economic damage per dollar […]
[…] As tax rates get closer and closer to the revenue-maximizing point, that means an increasing amount of economic damage per dollar […]
[…] As tax rates get closer and closer to the revenue-maximizing point, that means an increasing amount of economic damage per dollar […]
[…] favorite may be the one that pointed out why it generally is misguided to raise tax rates even if the government would collect more revenue […]
[…] to realize, though, that the Laffer Curve is very real. They may not like it, but there’s very strong evidence that imposing lots of taxes does not necessarily mean collecting lots of revenue. Especially when […]
[…] that it’s also a very bad idea to be at the “top of the Laffer Curve.” As noted in a study by economists from the Federal Reserve and the University of Chicago, that’s the point where economic damage is so great that a dollar of tax revenue can be […]
[…] it’s also a very bad idea to be at the “top of the Laffer Curve.” As noted in a study by economists from the Federal Reserve and the University of Chicago, that’s the point where economic damage is so great that a dollar of tax revenue can be […]
[…] I explained the Laffer Curve and tried to get across why high tax rates are a bad idea (even if they raise more revenue). As always, my top goal was to explain that a nation should not seek to be […]
[…] Needless to say, this doesn’t make sense. They are either clueless or hypocritical. But maybe if I accumulate enough example of “successful” supply-side tax hikes, they’ll finally realize it’s not a good idea to punish productive behavior. […]
[…] might boost revenue is not a selling point. Instead, it simply tells us that the rate should be further reduced. Remember, it’s a bad idea to be at the revenue-maximizing point on the Laffer Curve (though […]
[…] might boost revenue is not a selling point. Instead, it simply tells us that the rate should be further reduced. Remember, it’s a bad idea to be at the revenue-maximizing point on the Laffer Curve (though […]
[…] might boost revenue is not a selling point. Instead, it simply tells us that the rate should be further reduced. Remember, it’s a bad idea to be at the revenue-maximizing point on the Laffer Curve (though […]
[…] Such as this study by economists from the University of Chicago and Federal Reserve. […]
[…] that’s why the tax increases that generate more tax revenue are almost as misguided as the ones that lose […]
[…] somehow illegitimate because they’re based on back-of-the-envelope calculations, check out the very detailed and rigorous analysis from the European Central Bank that found an even larger negative relationship between tax revenue and foregone economic […]
[…] illegitimate because they’re based on back-of-the-envelope calculations, check out the very detailed and rigorous analysis from the European Central Bank that found an even larger negative relationship between tax revenue and foregone economic […]
[…] First, you presumably shouldn’t want to be at the revenue-maximizing point of the Laffer Curve. Unless, of course, you think giving politicians an extra $1 to spend is worth destroying $5 or $10 of income for households. […]
[…] First, you presumably shouldn’t want to be at the revenue-maximizing point of the Laffer Curve. Unless, of course, you think giving politicians an extra $1 to spend is worth destroying $5 or $10 of income for households. […]
[…] In any event, my modest hope is that politicians will learn that higher tax rates lead to less taxable income. Whether taxable income falls by a lot or a little obviously depends on the specific circumstance. But in either case, I want policy makers to understand that there are negative economic effects. […]
[…] spite that they favor high tax rates on the “rich” even if the net effect (because of diminished economic output) is less revenue for […]
[…] previously cited academic research and expert analysis to show that it is pointlessly punitive to raise tax rates if the damage to the private sector is […]
[…] previously cited academic research and expert analysis to show that it is pointlessly punitive to raise tax rates if the damage to the private sector is […]
[…] Only a fool (or a malicious person) wants to be at the revenue-maximizing point of the Laffer Curve. The right goal is to set tax rates at the growth-maximizing […]
[…] Only a fool (or a malicious person) wants to be at the revenue-maximizing point of the Laffer Curve. The right goal is to set tax rates at the growth-maximizing […]
[…] revenue. Yet that’s the answer from the JCT. Moreover, the Laffer Curve also shows that tax increases can impose very high economic costs even if they do raise revenue, so the value of using such analysis is not driven by whether revenues go up or […]
[…] revenue. Yet that’s the answer from the JCT. Moreover, the Laffer Curve also shows that tax increases can impose very high economic costs even if they do raise revenue, so the value of using such analysis is not driven by whether revenues go up or […]
[…] revenue. Yet that’s the answer from the JCT. Moreover, the Laffer Curve also shows that tax increases can impose very high economic costs even if they do raise revenue, so the value of using such analysis is not driven by whether revenues go up or […]
[…] revenue coming from any taxpayers. If tax rates are near the revenue-maximizing point, it implies a huge loss of private output per additional dollar collected by […]
[…] of our well-read readers directed me to a blog post by Daniel Mitchell, a senior fellow at the Cato Institute, through which I found this […]
[…] to the revenue-maximizing point, the economic damage becomes very significant. Here’s some of what I wrote about that topic back in […]
[…] to the revenue-maximizing point, the economic damage becomes very significant. Here’s some ofwhat I wrote about that topic back in […]
[…] to the revenue-maximizing point, the economic damage becomes very significant. Here’s some of what I wrote about that topic back in […]
[…] to the revenue-maximizing point, the economic damage becomes very significant. Here’s some of what I wrote about that topic back in […]
[…] P.P.P.S. Above all else, never forget that the goal should be to maximize growth rather than revenues. That’s because we want small government. But even for those that don’t want small government, you don’t want to be near the revenue-maximizing point of the Laffer Curve since that implies significant economic damage per every dollar collected. […]
[…] So if Mr. de Blasio wins and succeeds in pushing through his tax agenda, don’t expect to see much – if any – additional revenue. This will be a tailor-made example of the Laffer Curve in action. […]
[…] estimate changes in tax revenues simply by looking at changes in tax rates. You also have to consider changes in taxable income. Only a fool, for instance, would assume that you can double tax revenue by doubling tax […]
[…] estimate changes in tax revenues simply by looking at changes in tax rates. You also have to consider changes in taxable income. Only a fool, for instance, would assume that you can double tax revenue by doubling tax […]
Who cares? Taxation is theft. The end.
[…] Such as this study by economists from the University of Chicago and Federal Reserve. […]
[…] Such as this study by economists from the University of Chicago and Federal Reserve. […]
[…] Such as this study by economists from the University of Chicago and Federal Reserve. […]
[…] why you’re much better off looking at this research from economists at the University of Chicago and the Federal Reserve. Heck, even the IMF is acknowledging that it’s self-defeating to raise tax rates in a nation like […]
[…] Such as this study by economists from the University of Chicago and Federal Reserve. […]
[…] Such as this study by economists from the University of Chicago and Federal Reserve. […]
[…] Such as this study by economists from the University of Chicago and Federal Reserve. […]
[…] Such as this study by economists from the University of Chicago and Federal Reserve. […]
[…] The Laffer Curve Shows that Tax Increases Are a Very Bad Idea – even if They Generate More Tax Re… […]
[…] The Laffer Curve Shows that Tax Increases Are a Very Bad Idea – even if They Generate More Tax Re… […]
[…] Such as this study by economists from the University of Chicago and Federal Reserve. […]
[…] other words, even if you’re a leftist and your main goal is giving the government more revenue, higher tax rates are a bad idea. The rich will simply figure out ways to protect their earnings while the rest of us suffer because […]
[…] why you’re much better off looking at this research from economists at the University of Chicago and the Federal Reserve. Heck, even the IMF is acknowledging that it’s self-defeating to raise tax rates in a nation like […]
[…] why you’re much better off looking at this research from economists at the University of Chicago and the Federal Reserve. Heck, even the IMF is acknowledging that it’s self-defeating to raise tax rates in a nation […]
[…] Curve, particularly in hopes that I will educate lawmakers that higher tax rates are a bad idea – even if they wind up generating additional […]
[…] particularly in hopes that I will educate lawmakers that higher tax rates are a bad idea – even if they wind up generating additional […]
[…] other words, even if you’re a leftist and your main goal is giving the government more revenue, higher tax rates are a bad idea. The rich will simply figure out ways to protect their earnings while the rest of us suffer because […]
[…] words, even if you’re a leftist and your main goal is giving the government more revenue, higher tax rates are a bad idea. The rich will simply figure out ways to protect their earnings while the rest of us suffer because […]
I have not found the paper, so the curves require some explanation.
Mr. Mitchell’s point aside about the exorbitant Rahn curve effect (and thus detriment to long term prosperity) of pursuing small increases in tax revenue along the depicted curves,
The curves seem to imply that a sum invested, which may earn a, say 5% return (a realistic average expected long term return form a somewhat risky investment such as a stock fund — though not in a 60% tax economy, but that is yet another story) then after applying the 60% Laffer Max tax rate, the investment return would be reduced to a below inflation return of just over 2% — therefore, in essence turning the return on investment negative and implying that the “investment” would return less and less as time goes by.
And the implication is that people would still invest in such a climate, thereby engaging in delayed gratification with ever diminishing reward at the end???? “Please invest so that not only you what to wait for your reward, but also get less in the end???”” seems rather absurd.
What is the investor’s incentive to delayed gratification if after a ten-twenty year wait you get a lesser house, lesser car lesser whatever than you would have started enjoying right of the bat in your youth?
Capital formation, i.e. delayed gratification (for a reward of course) is essential to economic growth under any economic theory, even Marxism as Mr. Mitchell often reminds.
Am I interpreting wrong, or am I too selfish to comprehend the curves?
But if the average person is that much different than I am then, heck, I’d sure like to know. I’d be happy to bail out and live out of other people’s 60% tax allowance.
I don’t need much. Just give me a 60% tax financed surfboard, a 60% tax financed modest dwelling, a 60% tax financed cheap public transportation system, 60% tax financed “free” healthcare and I’m happy. I’ll even buy the guitar and pay for the yoga lessons myself! Actually had you told me earlier, I would have dropped out of high school long ago. No need to break my head trying to find therapies to currently incurable diseases, especially when everyone else has so far failed at same attempt. I’ll leave that to the motivated and 60% taxed employees of the общественный институт здоровья. Sun and beach are awaiting…
You might wish to update the post with a link to the pape, which appears to be here:
Click to access c12638.pdf
My initial reaction is the same as Zorba’s, to wonder about the effect of growth on future revenues. I wonder if rather than merely a “snapshot” of revenues, if there is any work done showing e.g. the 10 or 50 or 100 year revenue potential given the compounding effect of a higher growth rate. Obviously we wish lower taxes regardless, but it can’t hurt to be able to indicate to statists they’d get more revenue in the future if they lower taxes now (e.g. to deal with future entitlement issues). Of course we don’t want them to keep that extra revenue, but thats a separate issue 🙂
On a lighter note, collectivists are engaging in HOPE that they can CHANGE the shape of the Rahn curve. Step number one is to play “imagine” by John Lennon ten times every morning while you drive to work in your Prius.
I do not wish to completely ridicule the approach, some minor changes are possible. But I think that excluding some fleeting youthful enthusiasm, the desire to leave family and leisure at home to go work for distant unknowns wears out pretty quickly. Alas, lemmings will keep trying – and force you to participate too. “It takes a village”. Or rather “This is the village. Participation is mandatory”. And decline assured.
Reblogged this on Brian Albrecht.
Have not read the paper. However the description of “steady state” is either incorrect or misleading. Steady state what? Over 5-10-20 years?
Because in the long term the compounding effects of growth (or lack thereof) become the dominant factors even in tax revenue. Eventually, given enough time, growth rate dwarfs all other effects.
Stated in perhaps slightly more elegant mathematical form I would propose the following Zorba’s lemma:
“In the longer term, the Laffer curve converges to the Rahn curve.”
In other words, in the long term, the taxation point that maximizes tax revenue is the same taxation point that maximizes growth. Think about it over some back envelope scribblings with someone mathematically minded and you will come to same conclusion.
Reblogged this on Common Sense and commented:
It was true in the eighties and still true today! The Reagan revolution !!!!
Nicely presented, Dan. You make a complex point accessible and understandable. i am currently doing some research on the spending side of government and its relation to growth in standard of living. It’s only partly done and there is still quite a bit of work to do, but one of the preliminary results actually corroborates a key point you make. My data shows that once government spending grows to 40 percent of GDP, the standard of living virtuall grinds to a halt. The relationship between spending at lower-than-40 percent of GDP and the standard of living appears to be one of diminishing returns, much in the same way as the data you present here shows diminishing returns on tax revenues as you jack up taxes. The only problem with studying the relationship between small governments and any other economic variable is that there aren’t a whole lot of observations of small governments available… You can get some clear and visible results from what is out there, they just won’t hold up in the court of rigorous statistics.
Reblogged this on Public Secrets and commented:
Trouble is, facts and empirical evidence mean little to statists.