It’s relatively easy to demonstrate how certain regulations make our lives less pleasant (inferior light bulbs, substandard toilets, inadequate washing machines, crummy dishwashers, etc).
Furthermore, it’s also simple to highlight examples of foolish and preposterous regulations.
And it’s a straightforward exercise (at least conceptually) to argue that regulations should pass some sort of cost-benefit test.
What’s not so easy, however, is getting folks to grasp the overall impact of red tape on growth and living standards. After all, most normal people don’t want to learn about wonky concepts such as the production possibilities frontier. And I also doubt there are many people who are interested in the technical challenge of how to measure the aggregate impact of thousand of rules and restrictions.
But these issues matter. A lot. According to Economic Freedom or the World, the regulatory burden is just as important as the fiscal burden when determining a nation’s competitiveness and economic outlook. Simply stated, our living standards are determined by productivity, which is determined by how wisely labor and capital are combined to generate output.
With this in mind, a new study from the European Central Bank helpfully examines the degree to which regulation hinders the efficient allocation of those factors of production.
The focus of this paper is on the…misallocation of labour and capital in eight macro-sectors (which include manufacturing and services) for five large euro-area countries (Belgium, France, Germany, Italy and Spain) during the period 2002-2012.
…The paper then investigates the potential determinants of changes in input misallocation by looking at traditional structural determinants, namely restrictive product and labour market regulations. …regulations that shelter firms from competition might result in poor allocation of resources because low productive firms will keep operating instead of downsizing or exiting. Similarly, stringent labour market regulation, in the form of high hiring and firing costs, might also thwart resource allocation.
For those who are interested in such things, the study looks at what drives improvements in productivity. Is it firms becoming more efficient because of competition, or is “reallocation” as weak companies vanish and dynamic new firms emerge?
The short answer, as illustrated by the table, is that both play a role.
Here are some of the issues considered in the ECB study.
In our full empirical specification, as well as initial conditions in misallocation, …we first examine the role of two structural factors, i.e. changes in both product and labour market regulations. In the presence of high barriers to entry, unproductive firms are able to survive and therefore retain productive resources which are not shifted to the most efficient firms in a given industry (Schiantarelli 2008; Restuccia and Rogerson 2013; Andrews and Cingano 2014). Furthermore, more stringent employment regulation might prevent firms from adjusting their workforce to optimal levels, therefore hampering the efficient reallocation of workers across firms (Haltiwanger, Scarpetta and Schweizer 2014; Bartelsman, Gautier and de Wind 2011). Moreover, in the labour misallocation regressions we also include an interaction term between the changes in product and labour market regulations.
Here are their estimates of both product market regulation and labor market regulation for selected nations.
It’s good to see that there’s a slight trend toward less regulation of product markets. A few nations have modestly reduced regulation of labor markets, but the most interesting observation is that this is an area where the United States has a major advantage. Only Germany is even close to America in allowing markets to operate with a high level of freedom.
Having examined the issues covered by the study, let’s now consider the results.
All discussed capital misallocation results are robust to the inclusion of market distortions, i.e. to regulatory and credit constraints. …The general decline in PMR over the period considered dampened capital misallocation dynamics… Stricter product market regulation is found to have led to higher labour misallocation growth. But we also find that more stringent labour market regulations positively correlate with labour misallocation growth, particularly in sectors characterized by more stringent product market regulations. Thus, these results support the idea that the positive effect of the tightness of PMR on labour misallocation growth is amplified if also EPL becomes more restrictive. Seen from an inverse perspective, the gains in the allocative efficiency of labour are larger if both kinds of regulation are jointly loosened.
Here’s the bottom line.
Our results therefore suggest that in order to foster a more efficient within-sector allocation of inputs across firms structural reforms, such as those lowering entry barriers for firms, removing size-contingent regulations that prevent firms from reaching their optimal size and enhancing bankruptcy regulations that facilitate the exit of unproductive firms, would be warranted. The loosening of PMR and EPL in recent years in some countries has proven to dampen misallocation dynamics, yet there is still room for further reductions, as shown for example when comparing the level of regulation with that in the U.S.
Unfortunately, I don’t expect that this study will have any sort of impact on the debate. The people who already understand the negative impact of regulation now have more evidence about the value of unfettered markets and creative destruction.
But the politicians and interest groups won’t care. They are interested in accumulating power and obtaining unearned benefits. To the extent that they would even bother to read the study, they would conclude that they should fight extra hard to preserve the status quo since they will realize that there are fewer favors to distribute when genuine capitalism is allowed to operate.
[…] nanny-state crowd in DC generates red tape with big macroeconomic costs. But also quality-of-life […]
[…] a lesson we can apply to all sorts of other issues involving government intervention (housing subsidies, […]
[…] on the latest available data on key indicators such as taxes, spending, regulation, trade policy, rule of law, and monetary policy, here are the top-20 […]
[…] on the latest available data on key indicators such as taxes, spending, regulation, trade policy, rule of law, and monetary policy, here are the top-20 […]
[…] Before addressing the three myths mentioned in the video, it’s worth noting that there’s a technical definition of socialism based on policies such as government ownership, central planning, and price controls, and a casual definition of socialism based on policies such as punitive tax rates, welfare state, and intervention. […]
[…] Before addressing the three myths mentioned in the video, it’s worth noting that there’s a technical definition of socialism based on policies such as government ownership, central planning, and price controls, and a casual definition of socialism based on policies such as punitive tax rates, welfare state, and intervention. […]
[…] I write about regulation, I usually focus on big-picture issues involving economic costs, living standards, […]
[…] Regulatory policy will move in the wrong direction. […]
[…] and price controls) or the casual definition of socialism (punitive tax rates, welfare state, intervention), the ideology has a track record of […]
[…] Regulatory policy will move in the wrong direction. […]
[…] Regulatory policy will move in the wrong direction. […]
[…] Regulatory policy will move in the wrong direction. […]
[…] Regulatory policy will move in the wrong direction. […]
[…] is whether proposed regulations generate enough benefits to justify the added expense (I’m generally skeptical, but those are empirical […]
[…] more “breathing room” to start businesses and create jobs. Which is why the scholarly evidence shows that less regulation is good for […]
[…] true about taxes. That’s true about spending. That’s true about regulation. And it’s true about […]
[…] they push for regulations and taxes that hinder creative destruction. And that means less long-run prosperity for all of […]
[…] European Central Bank estimated that product market and employment regulation has led to costly “misallocation of labour and capital […]
[…] it definitely has the highest percentage of quality research (see here, here, here, here, here, and here for […]
[…] also studies on the adverse impact of regulation, bureaucracy, and […]
[…] European Central Bank estimated that product market and employment regulation has led to costly “misallocation of labour and […]
[…] Speaking of economic impact, a study from the European Central Bank had some very sobering […]
[…] are many factors that determine a nation’s economic success, including trade policy, regulation, monetary policy, and rule of law, so a good tax code isn’t a guarantor of prosperity and a […]
[…] I write about regulation, I usually focus on big-picture issues involving economic costs, living standards, and […]
[…] I write about regulation, I usually focus on big-picture issues involving economic costs, living standards, and […]
[…] I write about regulation, I usually focus on big-picture issues involving economic costs, living standards, and […]
[…] I write about regulation, I usually focus on big-picture issues involving economic costs, living standards, and […]
[…] less regulation is an important ingredient in the recipe for growth and prosperity. And nations that do a better job of following that recipe […]
[…] If you want some wonky analysis of regulation, I have some detailed columns here, here, here, here, here, here, and […]
[…] If you want some wonky analysis of regulation, I have some detailed columns here, here, here, here, here, here, and […]
This is why I think Mr Trump’s budget will be good for the economy, even though it doesn’t cut total spending. In the worst case, military spending is useless. If we are not attacked and don’t need a military, then every dollar we spend paying soldiers to sit around doing nothing is a dollar lost, but that’s the end of the story. Every dollar spent on regulatory agencies, though, is not just a dollar lost, but a dollar spent to actively hurt the economy. Spending $1 on a regulatory agency costs us more than $1: we lost the dollar given to the bureaucrats, and then on top of that we lost additional dollars in lost productivity, lost potential, and squandered wealth.
So if Mr Trump’s budget succeeds in moving money from regulatory agencies to the military, even if total spending remains the same, the economy will be better off.