One of the more elementary observations about economics is that a nation’s prosperity is determined in part by the quantity of quality of labor and capital. These “factors of production” are combined to generate national income.
I frequently grouse that punitive tax policies discourage capital. There’s less incentive to invest, after all, if the government imposes extra layers of tax on income that is saved and invested.
Bad tax laws also discourage labor. High marginal tax rates penalize people for being productive, and this can be especially counterproductive for entrepreneurship and innovation.
Though we shouldn’t overlook how government discourages low-income people from being productively employed. Only the problem is more on the spending side of the fiscal equation.
In today’s Wall Street Journal, John Early and Phil Gramm share some depressing numbers about growing dependency in the United States.
During the 20 years before the War on Poverty was funded, the portion of the nation living in poverty had dropped to 14.7% from 32.1%. Since 1966, the first year with a significant increase in antipoverty spending,
the poverty rate reported by the Census Bureau has been virtually unchanged. …Transfers targeted to low-income families increased in real dollars from an average of $3,070 per person in 1965 to $34,093 in 2016. …Transfers now constitute 84.2% of the disposable income of the poorest quintile of American households and 57.8% of the disposable income of lower-middle-income households. These payments also make up 27.5% of America’s total disposable income.
This massive expansion of redistribution has negatively impacted incentives to work.
The stated goal of the War on Poverty is not just to raise living standards, but also to make America’s poor more self-sufficient and to bring them into the mainstream of the economy. In that effort the war has been an abject failure, increasing dependency and largely severing the bottom fifth of earners from the rewards and responsibilities of work. …The expanding availability of antipoverty transfers has devastated the work effort of poor and lower-middle income families. By 1975 the lowest-earning fifth of families had 24.8% more families with a prime-work age head and no one working than did their middle-income peers. By 2015 this differential had risen to 37.1%. …The War on Poverty has increased dependency and failed in its primary effort to bring poor people into the mainstream of America’s economy and communal life. Government programs replaced deprivation with idleness, stifling human flourishing. It happened just as President Franklin Roosevelt said it would: “The lessons of history,” he said in 1935, “show conclusively that continued dependency upon relief induces a spiritual and moral disintegration fundamentally destructive to the national fiber.”
In another WSJ column on the same topic, Peter Cove reached a similar conclusion.
America doesn’t have a worker shortage; it has a work shortage. The unemployment rate is at a 15-year low, but only 55% of Americans adults 18 to 64 have full-time jobs. Nearly 95 million people have removed themselves entirely from the job market.
According to demographer Nicholas Eberstadt, the labor-force participation rate for men 25 to 54 is lower now than it was at the end of the Great Depression. The welfare state is largely to blame. …insisting on work in exchange for social benefits would succeed in reducing dependency. We have the data: Within 10 years of the 1996 reform, the number of Americans in the Temporary Assistance for Needy Families program fell 60%. But no reform is permanent. Under President Obama, federal poverty programs ballooned.
Edward Glaeser produced a similar indictment in an article for City Journal.
In 1967, 95 percent of “prime-age” men between the ages of 25 and 54 worked. During the Great Recession, though, the share of jobless prime-age males rose above 20 percent. Even today, long after the recession officially ended, more than 15 percent of such men aren’t working.
…The rise of joblessness—especially among men—is the great American domestic crisis of the twenty-first century. It is a crisis of spirit more than of resources. …Proposed solutions that focus solely on providing material benefits are a false path. Well-meaning social policies—from longer unemployment insurance to more generous disability diagnoses to higher minimum wages—have only worsened the problem; the futility of joblessness won’t be solved with a welfare check. …various programs make joblessness more bearable, at least materially; they also reduce the incentives to find work. …The past decade or so has seen a resurgent progressive focus on inequality—and little concern among progressives about the downsides of discouraging work. …The decision to prioritize equality over employment is particularly puzzling, given that social scientists have repeatedly found that unemployment is the greater evil.
Why work, though, when government pays you not to work?
And that unfortunate cost-benefit analysis is being driven by ever-greater levels of dependency.
Writing for Forbes, Professor Jeffrey Dorfman echoed these findings.
…our current welfare system fails to prepare people to take care of themselves, makes poor people more financially fragile, and creates incentives to remain on welfare forever. …The first failure of government welfare programs is to favor help with current consumption while placing almost no emphasis on job training or anything else
that might allow today’s poor people to become self-sufficient in the future. …It is the classic story of giving a man a fish or teaching him how to fish. Government welfare programs hand out lots of fish, but never seem to teach people how to fish for themselves. The problem is not a lack of job training programs, but rather the fact that the job training programs fail to help people. …The third flaw in the government welfare system is the way that benefits phase outs as a recipient’s income increases. …a poor family trying to escape poverty pays an effective marginal tax rate that is considerably higher than a middle class family and higher than or roughly equal to the marginal tax rate of a family in the top one percent.
I like that he also addressed problems such as implicit marginal tax rates and the failure of job-training programs.
Professor Lee Ohanian of the Hoover Institution reinforces the point that the welfare state provides lots of money in ways that stifle personal initiative.
Inequality is not an issue that policy should address. …Society, however, should care about creating economic opportunities for the lowest earners. …a family of four at the poverty level
has about $22,300 per year of pre-tax income. Consumption for that same family of four on average, however, is about $44,000 per year, which means that their consumption level is about twice as high as their income. …We’re certainly providing many more resources to low-earning families today. But on the other hand, we have policies in place that either limit economic opportunities for low earners or distort the incentives for those earners to achieve prosperity.
I’ve been citing lots of articles, which might be tedious, so let’s take a break with a video about the welfare state from the American Enterprise Institute.
And if you like videos, here’s my favorite video about the adverse effects of the welfare state.
By the way, it isn’t just libertarians and conservatives who recognize the problem.
Coming from a left-of-center perspective, Catherine Rampell explains in the Washington Post how welfare programs discourage work.
…today’s social safety net discourages poor people from working, or at least from earning more money. …you might qualify for some welfare programs, such as food stamps, housing vouchers, child-care subsidies and Medicaid.
But if you get a promotion, or longer hours, or a second job, or otherwise start making more, these benefits will start to evaporate — and sometimes quite abruptly. You can think about this loss of benefits as a kind of extra tax on low-income people. …Americans at or just above the poverty line typically face marginal tax rates of 34 percent. That is, for every additional dollar they earn, they keep only 66 cents. …One in 10 families with earnings close to the poverty line faces a marginal tax rate of at least 65 percent, the CBO found. …You don’t need to be a hardcore conservative to see how this system might make working longer hours, or getting a better job, less attractive than it might otherwise be.
To understand what this means, the Illinois Policy Institute calculated how poor people in the state are trapped in dependency.
The potential sum of welfare benefits can reach $47,894 annually for single-parent households and $41,237 for two-parent households. Welfare benefits will be available
to some households earning as much as $74,880 annually. …A single mom has the most resources available to her family when she works full time at a wage of $8.25 to $12 an hour. Disturbingly, taking a pay increase to $18 an hour can leave her with about one-third fewer total resources (net income and government benefits). In order to make work “pay” again, she would need an hourly wage of $38 to mitigate the impact of lost benefits and higher taxes.
Agreeing that there’s a problem does not imply agreement about a solution.
Folks on the left think the solution to high implicit tax rates (i.e., the dependency trap) is to make benefits more widely available. In other words, don’t reduce handouts as income increases.
The other alternative is to make benefits less generous, which will simultaneously reduce implicit tax rates and encourage more work.
I’m sympathetic to the latter approach, but my view is that welfare programs should be designed and financed by state and local governments. We’re far more likely to see innovation as policy makers in different areas experiment with the best ways of preventing serious deprivation while also encouraging self-sufficiency.
I think we’ll find out that benefits should be lower, but maybe we’ll learn in certain cases that benefits should be expanded. But we won’t learn anything so long as there is a one-size-fits-all approach from Washington.
Let’s close with a political observation. A columnist for the New York Times is frustrated that many low-income voters are supporting Republicans because they see how their neighbors are being harmed by dependency.
Parts of the country that depend on the safety-net programs supported by Democrats are increasingly voting for Republicans who favor shredding that net. …The people in these communities who are voting Republican in larger proportions
are those who are a notch or two up the economic ladder — the sheriff’s deputy, the teacher, the highway worker, the motel clerk, the gas station owner and the coal miner. And their growing allegiance to the Republicans is, in part, a reaction against what they perceive, among those below them on the economic ladder, as a growing dependency on the safety net, the most visible manifestation of downward mobility in their declining towns. …I’ve heard variations on this theme all over the country: people railing against the guy across the street who is collecting disability payments but is well enough to go fishing, the families using their food assistance to indulge in steaks.
It’s not my role to pontificate about politics, so I won’t address that part of the column. But I will say that I’ve also found that hostility to welfare is strongest among those who have first-hand knowledge of how dependency hurts people.
P.S. If you want evidence for why Washington should get out of the business of income redistribution, check out this visual depiction of the welfare state.
P.S. The Canadians can teach us some good lessons about welfare reform.
P.P.S. The Nordic nations also provide valuable lessons, at least from the don’t-do-this perspective.
P.P.P.S. Last but not least, there’s a Laffer-type relationship between welfare spending and poverty.
[…] be influenced by economic policy. If there are generous government handouts, for instance, people may decide to work fewer hours. Or not at […]
[…] be influenced by economic policy. If there are generous government handouts, for instance, people may decide to work fewer hours. Or not at […]
[…] be influenced by economic policy. If there are generous government handouts, for instance, people may decide to work fewer hours. Or not at […]
[…] get $3000-plus for each kid, along with all the other goodies that are provided by Uncle Sam (often topped upby state […]
[…] get $3000-plus for each kid, along with all the other goodies that are provided by Uncle Sam (often topped upby state […]
[…] get $3000-plus for each kid, along with all the other goodies that are provided by Uncle Sam (often topped up by state […]
[…] bottom line is that the United States already has a big problem with government dependency. Per-child handouts will make a bad situation even […]
[…] But it obviously hasn’t been shared often enough with the crowd in Washington. Politicians have created a welfare state that penalizes work and rewards dependency. […]
[…] But it obviously hasn’t been shared often enough with the crowd in Washington. Politicians have created a welfare state that penalizes work and rewards dependency. […]
[…] an economist, I’m especially concerned that redistribution programs discourage employment. That’s bad for the economy. Even […]
[…] an economist, I’m especially concerned that redistribution programs discourage employment. That’s bad for the economy. Even more […]
[…] This article was reprinted with permission from International Liberty. […]
[…] are work requirements better than the status […]
“The 5 Big Problems with Andrew Yang’s $1000-a-Month Universal Basic Income Proposal”
“BY JOHN HAWKINS MARCH 11, 2019”
https://pjmedia.com/trending/the-5-big-problems-with-andrew-yangs-1000-a-month-universal-basic-income-proposal/
[…] It’s not just Social Security. Other programs also lure people out of the job market and into government dependency, with Obamacare being an especially harmful […]
[…] I think about social welfare spending, I mostly worry about recipients getting trapped in […]
[…] This article was reprinted with permission from International Liberty. […]
No reason for name calling.
You are in the business of renting property. Anyone who provides a service or sells a product runs a business. I’m sorry that I’m so far ahead of you that you don’t understand. Do you like what we’re doing now, or do you really believe we can go back to no safety-net support?
nedlandp says “Taxes would be collected by businesses, so employees would not have to file annual tax forms.”
Sounds good to me… I’m not an employee and I’m not a business… I collect rent from tenants,, so no tax forms and no tax payments,,,
Ned,,, you’re an idiot. ..
perhaps it would be beneficial to have some historical perspective on the days that led up to Johnson’s “war on poverty”… and what the Johnson’s real objective was….
Malcolm X on the Democrats in this Country:
The opportunity to be part of the main stream? Really?
Studies have shown that for every $ of state support some of the poor receive, the income they earn from employment will be reduced – sometimes by as much as $0.85 per $.
When will someone realise that for some people, there is a level of income that they want to earn and which allows them to exist. It is usually at a low level.
Not everyone wants to be part of the main steam.
Right now you have a federal and a state approach for support. I proposed that the federal plan should be a Universal Basic Income that would replace existing federal safety-net programs dollar for dollar, for those receiving support. For those earning income a UBI would replace the standard deduction and all tax deductions. For the wealthy, this would be the equivalent of capping their tax deductions; while the working poor would do better, without affecting the incentive to work, or the economics of hiring and firing (like minimum wage legislation would do). Those on benefits might see welfare disappear, those on unemployment and disability cut to be replaced by the UBI. Social Security would see no change, except two checks rather than one. Legal immigrants and working citizen minors would have the same flat tax, but a UBI equivalent deduction. The effective tax rate would be a smooth curve.
States could do as they please, knowing that all citizens are covered by a UBI at the poverty level. Some states would be liberal and have high cost of living, and would pay for such programs through higher taxes. Others would concentrate only on the incapable, with a targeted approach. Finally other states would let charities handle support above the UBI, with lower taxes.
The wealthy would pay for this only in a static view of the future.
In the dynamic view of the future, the UBI and a flat tax would make about 1 million bureaucrats unnecessary. Secondly, the tax code would be so efficient that the 8 billion man hours needed for compliance could be cut in half at least, to 4 billion man hours. Without tax consideration being such a big part of planning, decisions would be far more efficient.
Economic growth would be stimulated about 1 3/4%, from which the wealthy would receive the greatest benefit, which would play for the slight increase in UBI cost to wealthy tax payers.
Every citizen would face the same tax code: Income taxed a the flat rate, and a UBI payment received monthly. Taxes would be collected by businesses, so employees would not have to file annual tax forms.
Reblogged this on James' Ramblings and commented:
Reblogging for future reference (not total agreement)
In Alaska it is my observation that this also applies to our native population who have had this generational co game ran on them disguised as leftist compassion. Clean this up an you clean up a large portion of domestic abuse and substance abuse problems.