One of the interesting things I’ve noticed in my world travels is that supporters of free markets and small government generally are known as “liberals” everywhere other than North America.
I think the rest of the world has the right idea. After all, folks like Adam Smith are considered “classical liberals,” so it’s bizarre that “liberal” now is used to describe anti-capitalists in America.
To muddy the waters even further, it’s not uncommon for modern supporters of capitalism to be called “neoliberals.”
Though I wonder if that’s supposed to a be a term of derision. When I’m called a neoliberal in other countries, it’s always by someone who is criticizing my support for economic liberty.
Professor Dani Rodrik of Harvard, in a column for the U.K.-based Guardian, is not a fan of neoliberalism. He acknowledges that the term is ill-defined, but recognizes that it means a less power for government.
…neoliberalism…denotes a preference for markets over government, economic incentives over cultural norms, and private entrepreneurship over collective action. …The term is used as a catchall for anything that smacks of deregulation, liberalisation, privatisation or fiscal austerity.
…That neoliberalism is a slippery, shifting concept, with no explicit lobby of defenders, does not mean that it is irrelevant or unreal. Who can deny that the world has experienced a decisive shift toward markets from the 1980s on? Or that centre-left politicians – Democrats in the US, socialists and social democrats in Europe – enthusiastically adopted some of the central creeds of Thatcherism and Reaganism, such as deregulation, privatisation, financial liberalisation and individual enterprise?
Rodrik then proceeds with a lengthy discussion of the weaknesses and limitations of conventional economic analysis.
Much of what he writes is perfectly reasonable. The economy is not a machine and people are not robots, so mechanistic economic concepts – while useful – have limited value. Moreover, culture and institutions make a big difference, and it’s rather difficult to capture those concepts in economic models.
Moreover, he makes some interesting observations on how various nations such as China have liberalized in ways that defy easy analysis.
Which is certainly a fair point.
But then he finishes up his column with two examples that simply don’t make sense.
First, Rodrik cites Mexico as a supposed example of neoliberal reform.
Following a series of macroeconomic crises in the mid-1990s, Mexico embraced macroeconomic orthodoxy, extensively liberalised its economy, freed up the financial system, sharply reduced import restrictions and signed the North American Free Trade Agreement (Nafta). These policies did produce macroeconomic stability and a significant rise in foreign trade and internal investment. But where it counts – in overall productivity and economic growth – the experiment failed. Since undertaking the reforms, overall productivity in Mexico has stagnated, and the economy has underperformed even by the undemanding standards of Latin America.
My reaction is “huh?”
I spend a lot of time combing through international data in hopes of finding success stories to publicize and I’ve never come across anything to suggest Mexico is a good example. Instead, I found evidence a few years ago suggesting the country is a bad example.
Here’s the Mexican data from Economic Freedom of the World. You can certainly argue that Mexico did some good reforms in the late 1980s. But where’s the evidence for sweeping liberalization after the mid-1990s?
There was a very slight increase in Mexico’s score after 1995, which is better than nothing. But I’m not surprised that it didn’t yield impressive results since the rest of the world was liberalizing at a much faster rate.
Indeed, Mexico dropped from #49 to #69 between 1995 and 2000 because other nations were the ones with “extensive liberalization,” not Mexico.
Second, he takes a shot at Chile.
Chile’s neoliberal experiment eventually produced the worst economic crisis in all of Latin America.
“Huh?” would be an understatement. I was flabbergasted by this assertion.
But not the first part of that sentence. He’s correct that Chile is a poster child for market-friendly reform.
Here’s a chart from Economic Freedom of the World showing how the nation’s score dramatically improved between 1975 and 1995.
But I was shocked by the second part of the sentence. Chile had “the worst economic crisis in all of Latin America”?
Since I’ve written several times about the Chilean economic boom, I was totally baffled. What was Rodrik talking about?
So I took another look at a couple of sources to see if I had overlooked something.
Here’s the IMF data on per-capita GDP for Chile and the rest of Latin America. The numbers are only available back to 1980, but everything we see underscores my argument that Chile is a great success. It used to have living standards only slightly higher than the average for Latin America and now the people are more than twice as rich as their peers. If that’s a “worst economic crisis,” we should all be lucky enough to have similar problems.
Then I looked at the Angus Maddison dataset, which allows us to go back to 1970.
His numbers are adjusted for inflation, so the lines don’t rise as rapidly, but we see the same long-run pattern. Chile is getting richer at a much faster pace than other countries from Latin America. Once again, if this is a “crisis,” other nations should hope for a similar fate.
So what did Rodrik mean by “worst economic crisis”?
His article doesn’t provide any details, but if you look at the Maddison data for the early 1980s, there was a downturn, with per-capita output dropping in Chile from about $6,000 to about $5,000. And that reduction was noticeably larger than the average reduction for the rest of Latin America.
I’m guessing this is the supposed “crisis” that he mentions in the article.
But if that’s true, he’s guilty of an egregious example of “cherry-picking” data. Sort of like saying the record-setting 1998 Yankees were a failure because of a four-game losing streak in late August that year.
Honest analysis requires a look at the overall record, and all data sources show that Chile’s economic performance is far superior to its peers.
The bottom line is that Rodrik is on solid ground when he points out the limitations of conventional economic analysis. But when he then decides to criticize pro-market reforms, he concocts two examples that are – at best – sloppily inaccurate.
P.S. By the way, I can’t resist commenting on one additional assertion in Rodrik’s column.
The use of the term “neoliberal” exploded in the 1990s, when it became closely associated with…financial deregulation, which would culminate in the 2008 financial crash and in the still-lingering euro debacle.
This is another “huh?” moment.
The “neoliberals” were the people who opposed the policies – artificially low interest rates from the Federal Reserve and the corrupt Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac subsidies – that led to the financial crisis. And people like me were very opposed to the excessive government spending that led to the European fiscal crisis.
[…] What baffles me are the folks who try to argue that the reforms were a failure. See, for instance, Prof. Dani Rodrik and the New York […]
[…] What baffles me are the folks who try to argue that the reforms were a failure. See, for instance, Prof. Dani Rodrik and the New York […]
[…] I suppose Mr. Faiola deserves some credit for cleverness. Some leftists have tried to argue Chile is a failed “neoliberal experiment.” Given the nation’s superior performance, that’s […]
[…] What baffles me are the folks who try to argue that the reforms were a failure. See, for instance, Prof. Dani Rodrik and the New York […]
[…] I suppose Mr. Faiola deserves some credit for cleverness. Some leftists have tried to argue Chile is a failed “neoliberal experiment.” Given the nation’s superior performance, that’s […]
[…] folks on the left (including editors at the New York Times) bizarrely think Chile’s “neoliberal experiment” has been a failure. Given their upside-down perspective, they probably think Venezuela is a […]
[…] I suppose Mr. Faiola deserves some credit for cleverness. Some leftists have tried to argue Chile is a failed “neoliberal experiment.” Given the nation’s superior performance, that’s […]
[…] I suppose Mr. Faiola deserves some credit for cleverness. Some leftists have tried to argue Chile is a failed “neoliberal experiment.” Given the nation’s superior […]
[…] opined about Chile’s success and Venezuela’s failure on multiple occasions, but here’s the great José Piñera with an […]
[…] opined about Chile’s success and Venezuela’s failure on multiple occasions, but here’s the great José Piñera with […]
[…] What baffles me are the folks who try to argue that the reforms were a failure. See, for instance, Prof. Dani Rodrik and the New York […]
[…] What baffles me are the folks who try to argue that the reforms were a failure. See, for instance, Prof. Dani Rodrik and the New York […]
[…] statism to capitalist prosperity. Poverty has dramatically declined and Chile is now the richest nation in Latin America. Sadly, voters approved an initiative that could result in a new constitution […]
[…] if Chile is a failure, then other nations in Latin America must be in a far worse […]
[…] To be fair, the NYT editorial was merely misguided, which is better than the wild inaccuracy that has characterized some […]
[…] why do some anti-capitalist economists engage in absurd examples of cherry picking in failed efforts to discredit Chile’s […]
[…] Chile is easily the highest-ranked nation in Latin America, illustrating again the wisdom of pro-market reforms. […]
[…] Chile is easily the highest-ranked nation in Latin America, illustrating again the wisdom of pro-market reforms. […]
[…] P.S. Algunas personas han tratado de retratar a Chile como un fracaso, pero esas afirmaciones pueden desmentirse fácilmente. […]
[…] P.S. Some people have tried to portray Chile as a failure, but such assertions are easily debunked . […]
[…] P.S. Some people have tried to portray Chile as a failure, but such assertions are easily debunked . […]
[…] P.S. Some people have tried to portray Chile as a failure, but such assertions are easily debunked . […]
[…] P.S. Some people today have tried using to portray Chile as a failure, but this kind of assertions are quickly debunked . […]
[…] P.S. Algunas personas han tratado de retratar a Chile como un fracaso, pero esas afirmaciones pueden desmentirse fácilmente. […]
[…] P.S. Some people have tried to portray Chile as a failure, but such assertions are easily debunked. […]
[…] yourself which country offers more opportunity, especially for the poor? The obvious answer is Chile, where poverty has rapidly declined ever since the country shifted to free enterprise. In […]
If the USA economy is going down hill, Than what will you expect of such experiment. Soon or later they will experiment the same shity situation.
So behind the imperialism ideology, there is nothing good to be expecting.
If the USA economy is going down hill, Than what will you expect of such experiment. Soon or later thay will experiment the same shity situation.
So behind the imperialism ideology, there is nothing good to be expecting.
My theory is the term ‘neoliberal’ has taken off in Europe because it’s the economic wing of libertarianism which is a term that strikes fear into us irrational old-worlders.
Basically Western Europeans ( CH excepted ) tend not to want guns to protect themselves from governments. So in the UK we have neoliberal think tanks like the ASI and IEA but no libertarian ones of any note.
Great article again.
Rodrick, like so many others, believe that only a top-down organization of people’s time, talent, and treasury – by the knowledgeable elite few, will work. It is an arrogance and an ignorance of the highest degree. To quote Paul Krugman from 1998 “By 2005 or so, it will become clear that the Internet’s impact on the economy has been no greater than the fax machine’s.”
The sole opinion makers, by virtue of the interest and the real-world participants, have been taken out of the world of movie reviews, food, hotels, sightseeing, – when will it happen to the dodgy economists?
Another excellent post, as always.
great analysis and study of Rodrick’s assertions. I am not an expert in Latin America economics but if I were to make blind assumptions, the narco shadow would have something to do with Mexico’s overall stagnation and thus would make it the “cherry pickers” dream against liberal economic policies.
Chile’s economy “failed” to become socialist.