Mancur Olson (1932-1998) was a great economist who came up with a very useful analogy to help explain the behavior of many governments. He pointed out that a “roving bandit” has an incentive to maximize short-run plunder by stealing everything from victims (i.e. a 100 percent tax rate), whereas a “stationary bandit” has an incentive to maximize long-run plunder by stealing just a portion of what victims produce every year (i.e., the revenue-maximizing tax rate).
Tyler Cowen of George Mason University elaborates on this theory in this very helpful video.
As you can see, Olson’s theory mostly is used to analyze and explain the behavior of autocratic governments. Now let’s apply these lessons to political behavior in modern democracies.
I wrote last year about a field of economic theory called “public choice” to help explain how and why the democratic process often generates bad results. Simply stated, politicians and special interests have powerful incentives to use government coercion to enrich themselves while ordinary taxpayers and consumers have a much smaller incentive to fight against that kind of plunder.
But what’s the best way to think about these politicians and interest groups? Are they roving bandits or stationary bandits?
The answer is both. To the extent that they think their power is temporary, they’ll behave like roving bandits, extracting as much money from taxpayers and consumers as possible.
Though if you think of democracies as duopolies, with two parties and rotating control of government, then each party will also behave like a stationary bandit, understanding that it’s not a good idea to strangle the goose that lays the golden eggs.
And this is one of the reasons why I’m a big fan of “tax competition.” Simply stated, politicians and special interests constrain their greed when they know that potential victims have the ability to escape.
Here’s a report from the Wall Street Journal that is a perfect example of my argument.
Germany could reduce its corporate tax rate in the wake of similar moves in the U.K. and the U.S., German Finance Minister Wolfgang Schäuble said. Europe’s largest economy should simplify its complex tax system for companies in order to…remain competitive internationally, Mr. Schäuble told The Wall Street Journal in an interview. He also said that while Germany opposed beggar-thy-neighbor tax competition between mature industrial nations, Berlin would also consider cutting tax rates if necessary.
And such steps may be necessary. In other words, Germany may reduce tax rates, not because politicians want to do the right thing, but rather because they fear they’ll lose jobs and investment (i.e., sources of tax revenue) to other jurisdictions.
U.S. President-elect Donald Trump has said he would like to cut the corporate tax rate from 35% to 15% as part of a broader tax overhaul. In November, U.K. Prime Minister Theresa May said the main corporate rate there should fall from 20% to 17% by 2020. These followed announcements about corporate tax-rate cuts by Japan, Canada, Italy and France.
Let’s look at another example.
I made the economic case for Brexit in large part because the European Union is controlled by anti-tax competition bureaucrats and politicians in Brussels.
Well, it appears that the British vote for independence is already paying dividends as seen by comments from the U.K.’s Chancellor of the Exchequer.
Philip Hammond warned yesterday that the Government will come out fighting with tax cuts if the EU tries to wound Britain by refusing a trade deal. …Yesterday, Mr Hammond was asked by a German newspaper if the UK could become a tax haven by further lowering corporation tax in order to attract businesses if Brussels denies a deal. In his strongest language yet on Brexit, the Chancellor said he was optimistic a reciprocal deal on market access could be struck… But he added: …‘In this case, we could be forced to change our economic model and we will have to change our model to regain competitiveness. And you can be sure we will do whatever we have to do. …We will change our model, and we will come back, and we will be competitively engaged.’ …Earlier this year Mrs May committed Britain to having the lowest corporation tax of the world’s 20 biggest economies. The intention is a rate of 17 per cent by 2020.
In other words, yet another case of politicians doing the right thing because of tax competition.
The stationary bandits described by Olson are being forced to adopt better tax policy.
So it’s very appropriate to close with some wise counsel from a Wall Street Journal editorial.
The EU needs more tax competition from government vying to stimulate business investment. …The real tax-policy scandal is that so few European governments understand there’s a cause-and-effect relationship between oppressive tax rates and low economic growth.
P.S. Since we’re looking at tax competition, Europe, and bandits, keep in mind there’s considerable academic work showing that Europe became a rich continent precisely because there were many small nations that competed with each other. Those jurisdictions felt pressure to adopt good policy because the various leaders wanted lots of economic activity to tax. All of which helps to explain why modern statists are so hostile to decentralization and federalism.
[…] For more public choice-related analysis, I recommend these three […]
[…] contrast, I view tax competition as a way of constraining the “stationary bandit” so that we don’t wind up with “goldfish […]
[…] If you want to understand the case for tax competition, click here, here, and […]
[…] by the fear that taxpayers can escape, I worry that short-sighted politicians (i.e., “stationary bandits“), will over-tax and […]
[…] it be nice if we lived in a society where good people didn’t have to worry about predatory politicians (and a world where bad people didn’t have the ability to steal from others by using […]
[…] to be more blunt, we need to restrain the “stationary bandit” that leads to “predatory […]
[…] contrast, I view tax competition as a way of constraining the “stationary bandit” so that we don’t wind up with “goldfish […]
[…] contrast, I view tax competition as a way of constraining the “stationary bandit” so that we don’t wind up with “goldfish […]
[…] contrast, I view tax competition as a way of constraining the “stationary bandit” so that we don’t wind up with “goldfish […]
[…] contrast, I view tax competition as a way of constraining the “stationary bandit” so that we don’t wind up with “goldfish […]
[…] bottom line is that we need tax competition to protect us from “stationary bandits” who would produce “goldfish […]
[…] bottom line is that we need tax competition to protect us from “stationary bandits” who would produce “goldfish […]
[…] I’ll close by emphasizing that the world needs tax competition as a necessary check on the greed of politicians. Without any sort of constraint, elected officials will over-tax and over-spend. […]
[…] the past couple of decades, I’ve been warning (over and over and over and over again) that politicians want to curtail tax competition so that it will […]
[…] contrast, I view tax competition as a way of constraining the “stationary bandit” so that we don’t wind up with “goldfish […]
[…] contrast, I view tax competition as a way of constraining the “stationary bandit” so that we don’t wind up with “goldfish […]
[…] competition” is another constraint on government greed. This is the premise that the “stationary bandit” of government won’t tax and spend as much when politicians know that people and […]
[…] tax competition is a very valuable check on the greed of politicians (a.k.a., the “stationary bandits“). Simply stated, governments no longer have unconstrained ability to tax and spend. Which […]
[…] video from Dan Hannan crams 10,000 years of human history into 5 minutes. We learn about the “stationary bandit” of government and find out how our ancestors endured pervasive oppression and […]
[…] oversimplifying, I explained that the pressure of tax competition was necessary to prevent “stationary bandits” from saddling nations with “goldfish […]
[…] line is that we should fight to protect tax havens and tax competition. The alternative is “stationary bandits” and “Goldfish […]
[…] theory also tends to generate some pithy concepts, such as “stationary bandit” and “predatory […]
[…] other words, he recognizes that “stationary bandits” should be cognizant of the Laffer Curve (i.e., high tax rates don’t lead to high tax […]
[…] cite Mancur Olson’s work on “political bandits” to understand the limited conditions that would be necessary for there to be a causal […]
[…] presentation, we will suffer from “goldfish government” unless tax competition exiss to serve as a constraint on the tendency of politicians to over-tax and […]
[…] with good reason. The Paris-based OECD has been trying to curtail tax competition in hopes of propping up Europe’s uncompetitive welfare states (i.e., enabling “goldfish […]
[…] Hannan explains how this led to the creation of governments, basically acting as “stationary bandits.” […]
[…] both sound like “stationary bandits” to me, but there are some […]
[…] Conference in Australia. I presented on tax competition as a means of controlling the “stationary bandit” of […]
[…] do I relentlessly defend tax competition and tax […]
[…] Needless to say, it’s utterly depressing that a Republican (in name only?) Treasury Secretary explicitly condemns tax competition. […]
[…] a big fan of tax competition because politicians (i.e., stationary bandits) are far more likely to control their greed (i.e., keep tax burdens reasonable) if they know […]
[…] is the same theory that the French and Germans use when trying to undermine tax competition. It’s supposedly unfair, they argue, when other countries have lower tax […]
[…] But. other than a much-too-short primer on growth and taxation from 2016, I don’t have something similar for tax policy. So I have to direct people to various columns about marginal tax rates, double taxation, tax favoritism, tax reform, corporate taxation, and tax competition. […]
[…] was also happy to see some results that bolster my argument in favor of jurisdictional competition as a tool to encourage better […]
[…] I have something even better because it confirms my hypothesis about tax competition being the most effective way of constraining greedy […]
[…] was also happy to see some results that bolster my argument in favor of jurisdictional competition as a tool to encourage better […]
[…] The moral of the story is that workers and investors benefit when money stays in the private sector. […]
[…] heading in the wrong direction, in large part because tax havens have been weakened and politicians no longer feel as much competitive […]
[…] I consider myself the world’s biggest advocate for tax competition and tax havens (even when it’s risky), I’m always on the lookout for new material to […]
[…] I consider myself the world’s biggest advocate for tax competition and tax havens (even when it’s risky), I’m always on the lookout for new material to […]
[…] income that is saved and invested. In effect, the battle over “tax havens” and “tax competition” were a proxy for whether there should be more double taxation and more extra-territorial […]
[…] will exacerbate the problem of too much government because the “stationary bandit” no longer will face competitive […]
[…] economists, by contrast, view tax havens favorably since they discourage politicians from over-taxing and over-spending (thus protecting nations from “goldfish […]
[…] But my final point is counter-intuitive. As much as I despise the actions of thuggish bureaucrats and politicians at the city and county level, I prefer local government over state government (or national government, or global government) for the simple reason that it’s much easier to escape their predatory behavior. […]
[…] Mexican government is a grim example of the “stationary bandit” in […]
[…] economist who described the unfortunate tendency of vote-seeking governments to behave like “stationary bandits,” seeking to extract the maximum amount of money from […]
[…] beleaguered private sector. That’s not a surprise. Indeed, it’s easily explained by the “stationary bandit” theory of government. But while the bandit of government may be stationary, the victims are […]
This article has helped me to see the explosion of police “civil asset forfeiture” as a not-so-subtle shift to *literal* roving banditry. What does this say about our government’s belief in the future of our country?
[…] not a surprise. Indeed, it’s easily explained by the “stationary bandit” theory of […]
[…] It doesn’t matter whether my speech was about tax reform, entitlements, fiscal crisis, or tax competition, most people wanted to know what I think about The […]
[…] stated, politicians are less greedy when they have to worry that the geese with the golden eggs can fly […]
[…] this new country. Here’s my speech, which begins with a discussion of government as a “stationary bandit” and then explores some of the theoretical issues of setting up a freedom-oriented […]
[…] is yet another example of why tax competition is something that should be celebrated rather than persecuted. It forces politicians to adopt better policy even when they don’t […]
[…] I’m a huge fan of tax competition because it pressures politicians to do the right thing even though they would prefer bad policy. […]
[…] I’m a huge fan of tax competition because it pressures politicians to do the right thing even though they would prefer bad policy. […]
[…] I’m a huge fan of tax competition because it pressures politicians to do the right thing even though they would prefer bad policy. […]
[…] When there are lots of competing jurisdictions, there’s pressure on all politicians to be rational stationary bandits rather than predatory roving bandits. […]
[…] When there are lots of competing jurisdictions, there’s pressure on all politicians to be rational stationary bandits rather than predatory roving bandits. […]
[…] other words, the “stationary bandit” couldn’t steal as much and that gave the private sector the breathing room […]
Thank you for publishing this excellent article. As good as it is, for me, the best part was your P.S. portion. You nailed it on hostility to decentralization!
Also, the comment from nedlandp is spot on. Corporate rates must be lowered to be competitive and allow US corporations to repatriate earnings, but its a smaller slice of the pie. Significantly reducing & simplifying personal income tax rates would create a larger positive economic result.
While I’m a big fan of cutting tax rates, much of the recent discussions relate just to the corporate tax rate. Corporations would be pretty short-sighted if they only focused on that one issue.
While the US is currently focused on the corporate rate, the lowering of that rate makes elimination of capital gains less likely, since the double taxation argument won’t work as well. If you want to make the country a tax haven, start first with taxes on investment.
Also, corporate tax payments are very small relative to personal income and payroll taxes. Since all taxes are rolled into the final price of the product or service, a cut in the corporate rate could be easily overwhelmed by “revenue stabilizing” increases in other rates.
Reblogged this on Elementary Politics News.