As we get deeper into an election season, many politicians feel compelled to discuss how to deal with poverty. And some of them may even be serious about trying to improve the system.
This hopefully will lead to big-picture discussions of key issues, such as why the poverty rate stopped falling in the mid-1960s.
If so, it helps to look past the headline numbers and actually understand the scope of the problem.
Nicholas Eberstadt of the American Enterprise Institute explains that the official poverty data from the Census Bureau overstates the number of poor people.
…the official poverty rate is a positive embarrassment today. The poverty rate manifestly cannot do the single thing it was intended for: to count the number of people in our country subsisting below a fixed and absolute “poverty line.” Among its many other shortcomings, this index implicitly assumes that a family’s annual reported income is identical to its spending power… But income and spending patterns no longer track for the lowest income strata in modern America. …the bottom quintile of US households spent 130% more than their reported pretax income. The disparity between spending and income levels for poorer Americans has been gradually widening over time.
Though the shortcomings of the Census Bureau sometimes largely don’t matter because advocates of bigger government arbitrarily choose different numbers that further exaggerate the degree of poverty in the United States.
In a column for National Review, the Heritage Foundation’s Robert Rector exposes the dishonest tactic (promoted by the Obama Administration and used by the OECD) of measuring income differences instead of actual poverty.
The Left often claims that the U.S has a far higher poverty rate than other developed nations have. These claims are based on a “relative poverty” standard, in which being “poor” is defined as having an income below 50 percent of the national median. Since the median income in the United States is substantially higher than the median income in most European countries, these comparisons establish a higher hurdle for escaping from “poverty” in the U.S. than is found elsewhere.
Based on honest apples-to-apples numbers, the United States is just as capable as other developed nations of minimizing material deprivation.
A more meaningful analysis would compare countries against a uniform standard. …Garfinkel and his co-authors do exactly that. They measure the percentage of people in each country who fall below the poverty-income threshold in the U.S. ($24,008 per year for a family of four in 2014). The authors reasonably broaden the measure of income to include “non-cash” benefits such as food stamps, the earned-income tax credit, and equivalent programs in other nations. They also subtract taxes paid by low-income families, which are heavy in Europe. …the differences in poverty according to this uniform standard were very small. For example, the poverty rate in the U.S. was 8.7 percent, while the average among other affluent countries was around 7.6 percent. The rate in Germany was 7.3 percent, and in Sweden, it was 7.5 percent. Using a slightly higher uniform standard set at 125 percent of the U.S. poverty-income thresholds, the authors find that the U.S. actually has a slightly lower poverty rate than other affluent countries.
These numbers probably disappoint leftists who want to believe that European nations are somehow more generous and more effective in dealing with poverty.
But Robert explains that advocates of smaller government and individual responsibility should not be happy because the federal government’s profligacy isn’t helping poor people become self sufficient.
It is, of course, a good thing that left-wing claims of widespread deprivation in the U.S. are inaccurate. But government welfare policy should be about more than shoveling out a trillion dollars per year in “free” benefits. When President Lyndon Johnson launched the War on Poverty, he sought to decrease welfare dependence and increase self-sufficiency: the ability of family to support itself above poverty without the need for government handouts. By that score, the War on Poverty has been a $24 trillion flop. While self-sufficiency improved dramatically in the decades before the War on Poverty started, for the last 45 years, it has been at a standstill.
Robert Doar and Angela Rachidi of the American Enterprise Institute make a very similar point about the welfare state failing to promote self sufficiency.
Recently released data show that the official poverty rate was 14.8% in 2014, only slightly below the 15% in poverty in 1970. And this is despite large increases in federal spending on anti-poverty programs. Spending on these programs has increased almost tenfold in constant dollars since the early 1970s and increased from 1.0% of GDP in 1972 to 3.8% in 2012… Where does this leave us? If helping people achieve self-sufficiency and be free of government assistance is the goal, the safety net has largely failed. But if reducing material hardship is the goal, it performs well.
I would make a very important change to the above passage. Doar and Rachidi write that the poverty rate hasn’t declined “despite large increases” in supposed anti-poverty spending. Based on the evidence, it would be more accurate to say that poverty has stayed high “because of large increases.”
Simply stated, when you subsidize something, you get more of it.
Anyhow, all this matters for three reasons.
- First, dependency is bad news for poor people, particularly when government subsidizes multi-generational poverty and unwed motherhood.
- Second, the current welfare state is bad news for taxpayers, who are financing a $1 trillion income-redistribution system that fails in its most important task.
- Third, the current system is bad news for the economy because millions of people are bribed to be out of the labor force, thus lowering potential output.
Let’s summarize what we know. The official poverty rate exaggerates the actual number of poor people by failing to properly measure income, but that may not matter much since proponents of more redistribution prefer to use dishonest numbers that are even more distorted.
And we also know that the welfare state is capable of redistributing lots of money, but also that it does a terrible job of promoting self sufficiency. Indeed, it’s almost certainly the case that massive levels of redistribution have had a negative effect.
So what’s the solution to this mess?
Folks on the left want even more of the same. But why should we expect that to have any positive effect? Indeed, it’s more likely that an expansion of the welfare state will simply lure more people into lives of sloth and dependency.
Some people on the right want to replace the welfare state with a guaranteed or basic income. This has some theoretical appeal, but it is based on the very shaky assumption that politicians could be convinced to completely repeal all existing redistribution programs.
Which is why the most prudent and effective step is to simply get the federal government out of the business of redistributing income and let state and local governments decide how best to deal with the issue.
This federalism-based approach has several advantages.
- Since redistributing income is not listed as an enumerated power, ending Washington’s role would be consistent with the Constitution.
This federalism model already has been successfully tested with welfare reform in the 1990s and it also is the core feature of proposals to block grant Medicaid.
- A state-based model is far more likely to result in the degree of experimentation, diversity, and innovation needed to discover how best to actually promote self sufficiency.
By the way, this federalist system may begin with block grants from the federal government (i.e., transfers of cash to state and local governments), but the ultimate goal should be to phase out such subsidies so that state and local governments are responsible for choosing how to raise funds and how to allocate them.
And once welfare is truly a responsibility of state and local governments, we have good evidence that this will lead to better policy.
[…] federalism has declined in the United States and we are getting worse results. But perhaps a restoration campaign would be politically successful. After […]
[…] federalism has declined in the United States and we are getting worse results. But perhaps a restoration campaign would be politically successful. After […]
[…] federalism has declined in the United States and we are getting worse results. But perhaps a restoration campaign would be politically successful. After all, welfare reform was […]
[…] such as socialismand fascism. And others such as corporatism and the welfare state, have undermined the benefits of free […]
[…] have caused immense damage, such as socialism and fascism. And others such as corporatism and the welfare state, have undermined the benefits of free […]
[…] to work, even if they can get $3000-plus for each kid, along with all the other goodies that are provided by Uncle Sam (often topped upby state […]
[…] to work, even if they can get $3000-plus for each kid, along with all the other goodies that are provided by Uncle Sam (often topped upby state […]
[…] to work, even if they can get $3000-plus for each kid, along with all the other goodies that are provided by Uncle Sam (often topped up by state […]
[…] most charitable answer is that they don’t want anyone to suffer from poverty and they mistakenly think big government can solve […]
[…] right approach is to get Washington out of the business of income redistribution. We’re far more likely to get good outcomes if we let states […]
[…] right approach is to get Washington out of the business of income redistribution. We’re far more likely to get good outcomes if we let states decide […]
[…] For what it’s worth, I think we’ll be most likely to get good results if we get Washington out of the redistribution business. […]
[…] The reason I’m conflicted is that the current welfare state—both in the United States and other developed nations—is bad for both taxpayers and poor people. […]
[…] The reason I’m conflicted is that the current welfare state—both in the United States and other developed nations—is bad for both taxpayers and poor people… […]
[…] The reason I’m conflicted is that the current welfare state—both in the United States and other developed nations—is bad for both taxpayers and poor people. […]
[…] The reason I’m conflicted is that the current welfare state – both in the United States and other developed nations – is bad for both taxpayers and poor people. […]
[…] points, particularly about how the welfare state actually undermined progress on reducing poverty and also eroded societal […]
[…] core argument is that the federal government does a very poor job of managing such programs, resulting in a maze of handouts that produce lots of fraud and […]
[…] people since state government would then have the ability and flexibility to design policies that help liberate recipients from government […]
[…] on homelessness and child poverty in New Zealand, but if their welfare state is anything like the mess in the United States, I wouldn’t be surprised to learn that the government is actually subsidizing destitution and […]
[…] on homelessness and child poverty in New Zealand, but if their welfare state is anything like the mess in the United States, I wouldn’t be surprised to learn that the government is actually subsidizing destitution and […]
[…] if you value individual liberty, you can drive yourself crazy thinking about all the foolish and counterproductive policies imposed by […]
Nedlandp, I fully agree with you.
[…] The “hope” part is my admiration of the private initiatives that are taking place and my semi-support for the local experiments that are taking place. I want poor people to have more money and I want them to have hope. And these experiments by private charities and local governments may teach us useful things that help us reform the very inefficient welfare states operated by central governments. […]
[…] The “hope” part is my admiration of the private initiatives that are taking place and my semi-support for the local experiments that are taking place. I want poor people to have more money and I want them to have hope. And these experiments by private charities and local governments may teach us useful things that help us reform the very inefficient welfare states operated by central governments. […]
[…] bring us back to the main policy lesson. We need to get Washington out of the business of redistributing income. To the extent government involvement is necessary, state and local governments should be […]
[…] bring us back to the main policy lesson. We need to get Washington out of the business of redistributing income. To the extent government involvement is necessary, state and local governments should be […]
[…] bring us back to the main policy lesson. We need to get Washington out of the business of redistributing income. To the extent government involvement is necessary, state and local governments should be […]
[…] whether it’s Medicaid, education, transportation, welfare, or disasters, involvement from Washington makes things worse rather than […]
[…] whether it’s Medicaid, education, transportation, welfare, or disasters, involvement from Washington makes things worse rather than […]
[…] experts who have looked at actual measures of deprivation have concluded that the real poverty rate in the United States is relatively low. Even when […]
[…] government shouldn’t be in the business of redistributing income, but that’s an issue we discussed a few days […]
Reblogged this on Public Secrets and commented:
Centralize everything in DC’s hands, if you want to achieve perfect mediocrity.
Current poverty programs have two aspects, financial and psychological. Financial needs are being met in the form of food, shelter, and healthcare. However, recipients are being crushed psychologically by dependence and disincentives to work.
The argument for a basic income is three fold: (1) A [monthly] cash distribution (a portion of which might go into a Health Savings Account) will force recipients to make decisions regarding their own welfare. While some may make poor decisions, these will self-correct in future months. (2) Since the basic income will be unrelated to income, disincentives will disappear. (3) Since a flat tax is politically unacceptable without some form of progressivity, its combination with a basic income makes the total package a political winner. [Note that 100% of the poverty line can go to all citizens, paid for by the $1 trillion in current means-tested programs plus the $1.4 trillion in tax deductions, from the current tax system.]
A basic income will also allow for elimination or repair of: welfare, unemployment and disability benefits, Medicaid, ACA, Medicare, and Social Security. For example, if a significant portion of Social Security is replaced by a basic income, there would be less risk in transitioning the remainder to private retirement accounts.
Block grants to states are a horrible idea. State programs are a big part of the current failed system. Funding would only grow current failed systems. The second problem with block grants will be the allocation problem. Obviously, states like New York will demand a higher per capita amount because of their higher cost of living.