When I first came to Washington back in the 1980s, there was near-universal support and enthusiasm for a balanced budget amendment among advocates of limited government.
The support is still there, I’m guessing, but the enthusiasm is not nearly as intense.
There are three reasons for this drop.
- Political reality – There is zero chance that a balanced budget amendment would get the necessary two-thirds vote in both the House and Senate. And if that happened, by some miracle, it’s highly unlikely that it would get the necessary support for ratification in three-fourths of state legislatures.
- Unfavorable evidence from the states – According to the National Conference of State Legislatures, every state other than Vermont has some sort of balanced budget requirement. Yet those rules don’t prevent states like California, Illinois, Connecticut, and New York from adopting bad fiscal policy.
- Favorable evidence for the alternative approach of spending restraint – While balanced budget rules don’t seem to work very well, policies that explicitly restrain spending work very well. The data from Switzerland, Hong Kong, and Colorado is particularly persuasive.
Advocates of a balanced budget amendment have some good responses to these points. They explain that it’s right to push good policy, regardless of the political situation. Since I’m a strong advocate for a flat tax even though it isn’t likely to happen, I can’t argue with this logic.
Regarding the last two points, advocates explain that older versions of a balanced budget requirement simply required a supermajority for more debt, but newer versions also include a supermajority requirement to raise taxes. This means – at least indirectly – that the amendment actually is a vehicle for spending restraint.
This doesn’t solve the political challenge, but it’s why advocates of limited government need to be completely unified in favor of tax-limitation language in a balanced budget amendment. And they may want to consider being more explicit that the real goal is to restrain spending so that government grows slower than the productive sector of the economy.
Interestingly, even the International Monetary Fund (which is normally a source of bad analysis) understands that spending limits work better than rules that focus on deficits and debt.
Here are some of the findings from a new IMF study that looks at the dismal performance of the European Union’s Stability and Growth Pact. The SGP supposedly limited deficits to 3 percent of GDP and debt to 60 percent of GDP, but the requirement failed largely because politicians couldn’t resist the temptation to spend more in years when revenue grew rapidly.
An analysis of stability programs during 1999–2007 suggests that actual expenditure growth in euro area countries often exceeded the planned pace, in particular when there were unanticipated revenue increases. Countries were simply unable to save the extra revenues and build up fiscal buffers. …This reveals an important asymmetry: governments were often unable to preserve revenue windfalls and faced difficulties in restraining their expenditure in response to revenue shortfalls when consolidation was needed. …The 3 percent of GDP nominal deficit ceiling did not prevent countries from spending their revenue windfalls in the mid-2000s. … Under the SGP, noncompliance has been the rule rather than the exception. …The drawbacks of the nominal deficit ceiling are particularly apparent when the economy is booming, as it is compatible with very large structural deficits.
The good news is that the SGP has been modified and now (at least theoretically) requires spending restraint.
The initial Pact only included three supranational rules… As of 2014, fiscal aggregates are tied by an intricate set of constraints…government spending (net of new revenue measures) is constrained to grow in line with trend GDP. …the expenditure growth ceiling may seem the most appealing. This indicator is tractable (directly constraining the budget), easy to communicate to the public, and conceptually sound… Based on simulations, Debrun and others (2008) show that an expenditure growth rule with a debt feedback ensures a better convergence towards the debt objective, while allowing greater flexibility in response to shocks. IMF (2012) demonstrates the good performance of the expenditure growth ceiling
This modified system presumably will lead to better (or less worse) policy in the future, though it’s unclear whether various nations will abide by the new EU rules.
One problem is that the overall system of fiscal rules has become rather complicated, as illustrated by this image from the IMF study.
Which brings us back to the third point above. If the goal is to restrain spending (and it should be), then why set up a complicated system that first and foremost is focused on red ink?
That’s why the Swiss Debt Brake is the right model for how to get spending under control. And this video explains why the objective should be spending restraint rather than deficit reduction.
And for those who fixate on red ink, it’s worth noting that if you deal with the underlying disease of too much government, you quickly solve the symptom of deficits.
[…] more surprising are that pro-spending cap studies from the International Monetary Fund (here and here), the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (here and here) and the European […]
[…] more surprising are that pro-spending cap studies from the International Monetary Fund (here and here), the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (here and here) and the European […]
[…] more surprising are that pro-spending cap studies from the International Monetary Fund (here and here), the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (here and here) and the European […]
[…] a practical perspective, balanced budget requirements are unsustainable because revenues rise and fall with the business […]
[…] a practical perspective, balanced budget requirements are unsustainable because revenues rise and fall with the business […]
[…] Ironically, economists at the IMF have written in favor of spending caps on multiple occasions. Too bad the political hacks in charge of the bureaucracy […]
[…] spending cap. There is a lot of evidence that spending caps work. That is not the case, however, with rules that seek to limit […]
[…] to have a Colorado-style spending cap. There is a lot of evidence that spending caps work. That is not the case, however, with rules that seek to limit […]
[…] also written about that research, citing studies by the International Monetary Fund (here and here), the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (here and here) and the European […]
[…] days ago, I explained that spending caps are better than anti-deficit rules. In this clip from the same panel discussion, I talk about how a spending cap should be […]
[…] days ago, I explained that spending caps are better than anti-deficit rules. In this clip from the same panel discussion, I talk about how a spending cap should be […]
[…] (with a frozen look) why spending caps (such as Switzerland’s “debt brake“) are better than balanced budget […]
[…] also written about that research, citing studies by the International Monetary Fund (here and here), the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (here and here) and the European […]
[…] also written about that research, citing studies by the International Monetary Fund (here and here), the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (here and here) and the European […]
[…] often produce high-quality research (see here, here, here, here, here, here, here, here, here, and here). Sadly, their sensible analyses doesn’t seem to have any impact on the policy […]
[…] contrast, the International Monetary Fund (twice!), the European Central Bank, and the Organization for Economic Cooperation and […]
[…] and they often produce high-quality research (see here, here, here, here, here, here, here, here, here, and here). Sadly, their sensible analysis doesn’t seem to have any impact on the decisions of […]
[…] and they often produce high-quality research (see here, here, here, here, here, here, here, here, here, and here). Sadly, their sensible analysis doesn’t seem to have any impact on the decisions […]
[…] of the problems with state balanced budget requirements is that tax revenues are very sensitive to economic […]
[…] often write papers pointing out the economic benefits of lower taxes and smaller government (and spending caps as well!). But the senior people at the bureaucracy (the ones selected by politicians) make all the […]
[…] in the research division of the IMF, and they periodically publish good research on topics such as spending caps, debt, decentralization, the size of government, demographics, government spending, and taxation. […]
[…] hope the political decision makers at the IMF read this study (as well as prior IMF studies on the efficacy of spending caps) and no longer will agitate for tax increases on nations that get into fiscal […]
[…] this. Even left-leaning international bureaucracies such as the International Monetary Fund (twice), the European Central Bank, and the Organization for Economic Cooperation and […]
[…] this. Even left-leaning international bureaucracies such as the International Monetary Fund (twice), the European Central Bank, and the Organization for Economic Cooperation and […]
[…] they occasionally are allowed to produce good research. I’ve favorably cited the bureaucracy’s work on spending caps, for […]
[…] are allowed to produce good research. I’ve favorably cited the bureaucracy’s work on spending caps, for […]
[…] International Bureaucracies Agree – Remarkably, the International Monetary Fund (twice!), the European Central Bank, and the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development […]
[…] le FMI produit parfois de bonnes analyses. Les économistes de cette bureaucratie ont conclu (à deux reprises !) que les plafonds de dépenses constituent la règle fiscale la plus efficace. Ils ont également […]
[…] that we sometimes get good analysis from the IMF. Economists from that bureaucracy have concluded (two times!) that spending caps are the most effective fiscal rule. They also made some good observations […]
[…] misguided, I’m going to classify my columns on spending caps as Part Va, Part Vb, Part Vc, Part Vd, Part Ve, Part Vf, Part Vg, Part Vh, Part Vi, and Part Vj of my fiscal-fights-with-friends […]
[…] Hong Kong and Switzerland. I even pointed out that international bureaucracies such as the OECD and IMF have admitted that spending caps are the only effective fiscal […]
[…] professional economists at the organization have concluded in two separate studies (see here and here) that expenditure limits produce good […]
[…] already highlighted how the International Monetary Fund (twice!), the European Central Bank, and the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development have […]
[…] IMF economists have concluded (two times!) that spending caps are the most effective fiscal rule, I really wonder whether the authors of the […]
[…] is one of the reasons I’m not a fan of a balanced budget amendment, Based on the experiences of American states and European countries, I fear politicians in […]
[…] already highlighted how both the International Monetary Fund (twice!) and the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development have acknowledged that spending […]
[…] It is a noteworthy development that even the OECD has embraced expenditure limits. Especially since the IMF also has endorsed spending caps. […]
[…] remember that this approach also has been lauded by the International Monetary Fund, which definitely is not part of the vast right wing […]
[…] earlier this month, I discussed another good IMF study that showed how deficit and debt rules in Europe have been a […]
And fundamental change can only come about by amending the Constitution. Term limits on Congress and federal judges, limits on tax and spending, and limits on the federal bureaucracy will change the culture in DC. The historical proof of the convention process is evidence that it works. It’ll take the grassroots movement to get our state legislators to enact the second phrase of Article V.
fundamentally change the way Washington does business…..
term limits………………………………..
It seems to me that the underlying problem is that either debt or spending constraints require the same Congress to pass them that they would be imposed on. If Congress was willing to pass spending constraints, presumably they’d be willing to just not pass huge spending bills. Relying on Congress to restrain it’s own spending is like saying that the solution to drug addiction is for the addicts to police themselves. If they were capable of doing that, there wouldn’t be a problem. The only alternative is a Constitutional amendment. But as we’ve seen on many issues, from gun control to warrantless searches, if the government doesn’t like something in the Constitution, they just ignore it.
The best approach is two pronged. First you must limit welfare and entitlement growth to less than growth of the economy. (I have dealt with this in previous comments.)
Next, you must limit Discretionary Spending to a percentage of GDP. There are two possibilities: A debt brake can be ignored in a “crisis”. Instead, provide for a bonus of 2x salaries if spending is below the target and nothing if above. Legislators are free to spend extra in a crisis, but they get no bonus.=
You’ll find that legislators will find a way to stay below budget.
After all they do work for us and should be rewarded for doing their job. LOL!!!
Your’re right about the nature of government to feed itself in good times and point fingers in bad. This is why the Convention of States Project is working on an amendment convention to limit spending and taxing, among other things. I haven’t seen you comment on this process yet.
[…] By Dan Mitchell […]