I’ve often complained that government-created third-party payer is the main problem with America’s healthcare system, and I was making that point well before Obamacare was imposed upon the country.
The issue is very straightforward. In a genuine free market, people pay “out of pocket” for routine expenses. And they rely on insurance only in cases where they may face large, unexpected costs.
But in our current healthcare system, thanks to Medicare, Medicaid, and the tax code’s healthcare exclusion, most of us buy services with other people’s money and that dramatically distorts incentives.
Here’s some of what I wrote about this messed-up approach back in 2009.
…our pre-paid health care system is somewhat akin to going to an all-you-can-eat restaurant. We have an incentive to over-consume since we’ve already paid. Except this analogy is insufficient. When we go to all-you-can-eat restaurants, at least we know we’re paying a certain amount of money for an unlimited amount of food. Many Americans, by contrast, have no idea how much of their compensation is being diverted to purchase health plans. Last but not least, we need to consider how this messed-up approach causes inefficiency and higher costs. We consumers don’t feel any need to be careful shoppers since we perceive that our health care is being paid by someone else. Should we be surprised, then, that normal market forces don’t seem to be working? …Imagine if auto insurance worked this way? Or homeowner’s insurance? Would it make sense to file insurance forms to get an oil change? Or to buy a new couch? That sounds crazy. The system would be needlessly bureaucratic, and costs would rise because we would act like we were spending other people’s money. But that’s what would probably happen if government intervened in the same way it does in the health-care sector.
As you can see, I’m frustrated.
I think the system is inefficient from an economic perspective. But I’m also a consumer, and I’m very dissatisfied whenever I have to deal with the healthcare system.
Fortunately, more and more people are adding their two cents on this topic.
Here’s some great analysis on the issue by Mark Perry of the American Enterprise Institute. He starts by pointing out how prices for health care generally climb much faster than the overall CPI price level.
Between 1998 and 2014 the price of medical care services in the US (as measured by the BLS’s CPI for Medical Care Services) has increased by 88.5%, or more than twice the 45.8% increase in consumer prices in general over that period… On an annual basis, medical care costs in the US have increased more than 4% per year compared to an average inflation rate of only 2.4% over the last 16 years.
He then explains that a big problem is third-party payer, which eviscerates normal market forces.
As a result, consumers are relatively insensitive to price, which means producers and providers can charge more and be relatively inefficient.
One of the reasons that medical care costs in the US have increased almost twice as much as general consumer prices since 1998 is that a large and increasing share of medical costs are paid by third parties (private health insurance, Medicare, Medicaid, Department of Veterans Affairs, etc.) and only a small and shrinking percentage is paid out-of-pocket by consumers. According to data from the Census Bureau, almost half (47%) of health care expenditures in 1960 were paid by consumers out-of-pocket, and by 1990 that share had fallen to 20% and by 2009 to only 12%. …Consumers of health care have no incentive to monitor prices and be cost-conscious buyers of medical services when they only pay 10% themselves, and the incentives of medical care providers to hold costs down are greatly reduced knowing that their customers aren’t price sensitive.
Mark then asks what the world would look like if the free market was allowed to function. And he identifies a niche in the healthcare system where that happens.
How would the market for medical services operate differently if consumers were paying out-of-pocket for medical procedures in a competitive market? Well, we can look to the $7.5 billion US market for elective cosmetic surgery for some answers.
And the information he shares is remarkable.
The table…shows the top five most popular surgical procedures and top five most popular non-surgical procedures for 2014, the number of each of those procedures performed last year, the total expenditures for each procedure, the average price per procedure both in 1998 and 2014, and the percent increase in price since 1998 for each procedure. …For the top ten most popular cosmetic procedures last year, none of them has increased in price since 1998 more than the 45.8% increase in consumer price inflation…, meaning the real price of all of those procedures have fallen over the last 16 years. …For three of the top five favorite non-surgical procedures in 2014 (botox, laser hair removal and chemical peel), the nominal prices have actually fallen since 1998 by large double-digit percentage declines of -23.6%, -31.2% and -30.1%. …none of the ten cosmetic procedures in the table above have increased in price by anywhere close to the 88.5% increase in medical care services since 1998.
Here’s Mark’s chart, and I’ve circled the relevant bits of data.
Just in case it’s not obvious, Mark then draws the should-be-obvious conclusions from this data.
Simply stated, when people spend their own money, they are careful shoppers. And when consumers are careful shoppers, that leads to competitive pressure on producers and providers to be much more efficient.
The competitive market for cosmetic procedures operates differently than the traditional market for health care in important and significant ways. Cosmetic procedures, unlike most medical services, are not usually covered by insurance. Patients paying out-of-pocket for cosmetic procedures are cost-conscious, and have strong incentives to shop around and compare prices at the dozens of competing providers in any large city. Because of that market competition, the prices of almost all cosmetic procedures have fallen in real terms since 1998, and some non-surgical procedures have even fallen in nominal dollars before adjusting for price changes. In all cases, cosmetic procedures have increased in price by less than the 88.5% increase in the price of medical care services between 1998 and 2014.
That last sentence is the key. Because of third-party payer, overall health care expenses have climbed about twice the rate of inflation.
For cosmetic surgery, where normal market forces operate thanks to an absence of government-imposed and government-subsidized third-party payer, prices climb slower than overall inflation.
Here’s a video, produced by the Center for Freedom and Prosperity, on the problem of third-party payer.
As you can see, Obamacare made the problem worse, but it’s just one small part of a really big problem caused by decades of government intervention.
P.S. The video expands upon the analysis provided in a previous CF&P video.
P.P.S. Setting aside the debate about whether it’s right or wrong, the abortion market also is an interesting case study of how prices don’t rise when consumers pay out of pocket.
P.P.P.S. Government-created third-party payer also is screwing up the market for higher education.
P.P.P.P.S. Mark Perry not only is a good economist, as you can see above, but he’s also a brave guy for being willing to antagonize feminists.
[…] idea of a British-style system. If you want to know the better approach, click here, here, here, here, here, here, and […]
[…] idea of a British-style system. If you want to know the better approach, click here, here, here, here, here, here, and […]
[…] and gluttons impose high costs on government health programs, maybe that’s yet another reason for restoring free markets in health […]
[…] gluttons impose high costs on government health programs, maybe that’s yet another reason for restoring free markets in health […]
[…] will be like putting toothpaste back in a tube. Even though there are some powerful examples of how healthcare costs are constrained when genuine market forces are allowed to operate, consumers will be very worried about shifting to a system where they pay directly for a greater […]
[…] I’ll close by pointing out that free markets work in health care when they’re allowed. Consider how we see rising quality and falling prices in the market for cosmetic surgery. Why? Because people are paying with their own money. […]
[…] Cox is definitely correct to use cosmetic surgery as an example of how free markets […]
[…] Cox is definitely correct to use cosmetic surgery as an example of how free markets […]
[…] illustrated by this data from Mark Perry, there are a few parts of the health care system where there’s little or no […]
[…] illustrated by this data from Mark Perry, there are a few parts of the health care system where there’s little or no […]
[…] the way, I can’t resist also calling attention to Mark’s data on what’s happened over time to prices for various health care services and […]
[…] the way, I can’t resist also calling attention to Mark’s data on what’s happened over time to prices for various health care services and […]
[…] the way, I can’t resist also calling attention to Mark’s data on what’s happened over time to prices for various health care services and […]
[…] are – privately provided (see examples for fire protection, money, roads, education, health, air traffic control, and […]
[…] And pervasive is no exaggeration. According to government data, nearly 90 percent of health care expenditures are paid for by someone other than the consumer. […]
[…] third-party payer causes higher prices in every sector where it exists and also pointed out that we see falling prices in the few parts of the healthcare sector where people actually buy with their own […]
[…] My typical response is to explain that I am a strong supporter of markets as the method to get high-quality roads, schools, and healthcare. […]
[…] Here’s how genuine free markets result in lower costs for […]
[…] I’ve made a similar case on several […]
To win the argument for free market healthcare, I think it would be more helpful to look at dermatology or physiatry and not cosmetic procedures because the left will make the case that the poor or middle class doesn’t need or can’t afford cosmetic procedures but all other healthcare should be accessible regardless of income hence should be a public good financed by tax payers. They won’t believe markets can find a way to provide care for all those in need. But perhaps that happens in dermatology. It’d be interesting to ask whether some dermatologists price discriminate because it seems they could if they aren’t bound by third party payer laws.
[…] other words, a free market can work in healthcare. And it gives us falling prices and transparency rather than bureaucracy and inefficiency. Maybe when they’ve exhausted all other options, […]
[…] other words, a free market can work in healthcare. And it gives us falling prices and transparency rather than bureaucracy and inefficiency. Maybe when they’ve exhausted all other options, […]
[…] if aren’t already numbed by lots of data, Mark Perry and Devon Herrick have more evidence of lower costs when third-party payer is […]
[…] if aren’t already numbed by lots of data, Mark Perry and Devon Herrick have more evidence of lower costs when third-party payer is […]
[…] will be like putting toothpaste back in a tube. Even though there are some powerful examples of how healthcare costs are constrained when genuine market forces are allowed to operate, consumers will be very worried about shifting to a system where they pay directly for a greater […]
[…] will be like putting toothpaste back in a tube. Even though there are some powerful examples of how healthcare costs are constrained when genuine market forces are allowed to operate, consumers will be very worried about shifting to a system where they pay directly for a greater […]
[…] will be like putting toothpaste back in a tube. Even though there are some powerful examples of how healthcare costs are constrained when genuine market forces are allowed to operate, consumers will be very worried about shifting to a system where they pay directly for a greater […]
[…] crisis by having most health care expenses directly financed by consumers (reserving insurance for large, unpredictable expenses). That new system should include all people, including politicians and their […]
[…] think about unsavory tax breaks such as the ethanol credit, the state and local tax deduction, and the healthcare exclusion. I have to remind myself that while these provisions are very odious, they should be repealed as […]
[…] From a regulatory intervention perspective, the law was bad news because it exacerbated the third-party payer problem. […]
[…] From a regulatory intervention perspective, the law was bad news because it exacerbated the third-party payer problem. […]
[…] Obamacare. We also need to deal with spending programs such as Medicare and Medicaid and address tax preferences and regulations that encourage […]
[…] car-buying example is great. I’ve previously tried to make the same point about third-party payer by using the examples of home insurance and car insurance, but I may have […]
[…] car-buying example is great. I’ve previously tried to make the same point about third-party payer by using the examples of home insurance and car insurance, but I may have […]
Our healthcare system has five problems: third-party payer, lack of unbiased advice, moral hazard induced risky behavior, uninsured pre-existing conditions, and cost lumpiness.
Dan’s article covered third-party payer, so I’ll touch on the other four.
Unbiased advice – Even if you had a free market in healthcare there is no source of advice to help you evaluate alternative treatments and their relative costs and success ratios. The doctor/patient relationship is asymmetric by its nature, and the doctor’s field of knowledge is limited. Referrals tend to be based on personal relationships.
Risky behavior – Weight, smoking, drinking, and high risk athletics, to name a few, would be reduced if the individual’s health costs reflected higher risks taken.
Pre-existing conditions – Since these conditions represent potential high costs to any insurance arrangement, they are a significant issue. However, given time, these conditions will disappear, if we have universal health coverage [not government]. Government involvement will have to continue for a period of time for those in need of coverage during the transition period.
Cost lumpiness – The average individual rarely sees a doctor until there is a crisis. Therefore, some pooling of resources is required to smooth costs for the average person and to moderate costs for those that develop chronic problems.
My answer for these and other problems is “Group Self-Insurance.”
Here’s a video explaining how it works:
Hi Dan
Kelly McCarthy here. From May I will be running a site called Self-RelianceCentral.com Currently it’s about prepper stuff but we’re going to expand it into government over-reach and other threats to personal liberty. We are about to take over the site and revamp it.
I wondered if you’d give me permission to run some of your articles. I’m not sure what your restrictions on redistribution are so I am following the Heritage model. I promise to cut and paste your exact article, use your headline and leave all links in. It would appear as it does now and be fully attributed. Basically I would be “sharing” by reposting it.
Are you OK with that?
Kelly
RE Dr Hencke’s comments: It’s certainly true that someone having a heart attack is not going to stop and search the Internet checking on prices for heart surgery at various area hospitals before he calls 911. Yes, the fact that some medical care is sudden and has life-and-death implications means that medical care probably always will have higher prices than other service requiring comparable resources, etc.
But it doesn’t make medical care immune to market forces if they were allowed to operate. Sure, if I was having a heart attack I’m not going to stop and price shop. But it would make a lot of sense to check out relative prices at area hospitals BEFORE you have an emergency, and then when it happens, you know where to go. If price information was readily available, I’m sure lots of people would do that. Not everyone, of course. But it doesn’t take everyone to force some price competition. There are people who are rich enough that they don’t care how much they spend on lunch, but that doesn’t mean restaurants can get away with charging $10,000 for a hamburger. There are enough people who DO care about the price to keep prices in check.
Ever have a water faucet break and water start spraying all over your house, or some other “plumbing emergency”? Maybe not life or death, but an emergency nonetheless. So why doesn’t the plumber get away with charging you $10,000 when you have a plumbing emergency? Because there are plenty of people who figure out which plumber has reasonable prices BEFORE the emergency happens, perhaps when they have non-emergency plumbing jobs, and so they know who to call when there is an emergency. And the plumber knows that if he tried to charge an outrageous rate when he saw you had an emergency, at the very least you would never call him again, problem warn your friends about him, etc.
Yes, in a free market, there can be factors that make it operate with less than perfect efficiency. But the free market is pretty resilient.
Good points, but as a physician for over 40 years I have a comment or two.
Agree that the problem arose with employer sponsored insurance after WW2 and the rise of governmental programs. Yes, the market does work for elective procedures not covered by insurance. However, as an emergency physician, I have to tell you that there is no bargaining to be had when you get appendicitis, a heart attack, or get hit by a drunk driver. You are pretty much stuck with what you get.
Hospital pricing is notoriously opaque. See the article in Time, “A Bitter Pill”, which described it well. As the hospitals buy up physician practices, lack of competition and additional hidden charges will increase.
Obamacare has not helped. It is the Unaffordable Care Act. My ER is now overflowing with non-emergency patients who have new, lousy insurance that few private docs will take as it pays so poorly. If you lose $5 on every patient you see, you can’t make it up in volume. So they come to us, with pimples, stubbed toes, and colds, while patients with abdominal pain are stuck in the waiting room waiting for a bed to open up. The govt clinics get FQHC funding which is supposed to cover care 24/7, but they keep bankers’ hours; we then see most of their patients. Capacity is also severely limited. Plus, there is no financial downside for govt enrollees using ambulances as taxis for bullshit reasons.
Hospitals need to make their charges a matter of public record. The law of unintended consequences has bitten hard and this is not being realized, as the requirements of Obamacare and of the EMR (electronic medical record) have increased administrative costs promulgating a huge rise in M&A activity, thus reducing the competition which is the essence of capitalism and sending these ridiculous prices even higher.
thanks for the column, Richard Hencke MD
On Thu, Apr 9, 2015 at 8:43 AM, International Liberty wrote:
> Dan Mitchell posted: “I’ve often complained that > government-created third-party payer is the main problem with America’s > healthcare system, and I was making that point well before Obamacare was > imposed upon the country. The issue is very straightforward. In a genuine > free m”
I couldn’t agree anymore ! My wife just went to the doctor for the first time in several years, the doctor ordered all types of bloodwork, but charged her insurance $250 for a 5 minute office visit. She just got a seperate bill from the lab for $380. This was done in the name of supposedly diagnosing her nerve pain in her feet. A similar situation occurred to me over a year ago, when I was sent to another pain specialist from my rheumatologist. The first office visit was around the same price, for perhaps 4 minutes, and to be written another prescription for a medication I told her I had been on years earlier. I’ve had 9 surgeries (three of them being back from an industrial accident, another, a work related and another when I was trimming trees in my yard, then there were two knee a shoulder and a stent being put in. She told me to try it again since it had been a few years. It still didn’t help, then I was sent to get $1,800 worth of X-Rays. Thanks to lieing doctors who always want more tests. I finally went to a naturopath, and don’t live in pain any longer.
[…] The competitive market for cosmetic procedures operates differently than the traditional market for health care in important and significant ways. Cosmetic procedures, unlike most medical services, are not usually covered by insurance. Patients paying out-of-pocket for cosmetic procedures are cost-conscious, and have strong incentives to shop around and compare prices at the dozens of competing providers in any large city. Because of that market competition, the prices of almost all cosmetic procedures have fallen in real terms since 1998, and WAIT, THERE’S MORE… […]
“Setting aside the debate about whether it’s right or wrong, the abortion market also is an interesting case study of how prices don’t rise when consumers pay out of pocket.”
That should be past tense. I will bet that prices will now rise as abortion coverage is now mandated by Obamacare.
Reblogged this on Public Secrets and commented:
Best thing we can do to rein in healthcare costs is a) Get rid of Obamacare and b) return insurance to its traditional roe of protection against catastrophe.