The modern welfare state is a disaster. But rather than go into lengthy details, let’s simply look at some very powerful images (click for enlarged view).
Probably the most damning evidence is that the poverty rate in America was steadily falling after World War II. But then Lyndon Johnson declared a “war on poverty” and got Washington more involved in the business of income redistribution. So what happened? The poverty rate stopped falling.
But it’s also sobering to see how much money is being spent on income-redistribution programs. Taxpayers at the federal, state, and local level are coughing up more than $1 trillion every year to subsidize poverty. To give an idea of how much inefficiency and waste permeates the system, this is enough to give every poor household $60,000.
Poor people are among the biggest victims of the welfare state. Redistribution programs create a dependency trap because of very high implicit tax rates on productive behavior. Simply stated, handouts are so generous that poor people who enter the labor force generally will have lower living standards than those who remain wards of the state.
So what’s the solution to this mess?
Fortunately, we have a case study that points us in a productive direction.
The Bill Clinton-era welfare reforms, pushed through by Republicans in Congress, were a big success. Here are some excerpts from an article written by an expert at the Brooking Institution.
Between 1994 and 2004, the caseload declined about 60 percent, a decline that is without precedent. The percentage of U.S. children on welfare is now lower than it has been since at least 1970. …More than 40 studies conducted by states since 1996 show that about 60 percent of the adults leaving welfare are employed at any given moment and that, over a period of several months, about 80 percent hold at least one job. …Again, these sweeping changes are unprecedented. …Equally important, with earnings leading the way, the total income of these low-income families increased by more than 25 percent over the period (in constant dollars). Not surprisingly, between 1994 and 2000, child poverty fell every year and reached levels not seen since 1978. In addition, by 2000, the poverty rate of black children was the lowest it had ever been.
This is an older article from 2006, so there was obviously some movement in the wrong direction after the recent recession.
Nonetheless, the big message from welfare reform in the 1990s is that blank-check welfare entitlements are greatly inferior to a federalism-based approach that allows states to innovate and experiment to see what works best.
That’s the good news.
The bad news is that the Clinton welfare reforms only addressed a minor part of the welfare state. Moreover, the Obama Administration has undermined some of the modest progress that was achieved in the 1990s.
So we need a new offensive to deal with the broader deficiencies of the current system, which is a disaster for both taxpayers and poor people.
But if we use Clinton’s welfare reforms as a model, there is considerable progress that can be achieved. Diana Furchtgott-Roth of Economics 21 has a new study on precisely this topic.
She identifies some of the major redistribution programs in Washington.
This paper examines the evolution of major U.S. welfare programs since 1998—shortly after the Personal Responsibility and Work Opportunity Reconciliation Act (PRWORA), the 1996 federal welfare reform signed into law by President Clinton, went into effect.
The paper chronicles the average amount of aid provided, as well as length of time on public assistance, focusing on the following programs: SNAP; Temporary Aid to Needy Families, or TANF (established by PRWORA); Medicaid; and Section 8 Housing Choice Vouchers (HCV).
And she points out these programs are an expensive failure, but proposes a way to address the problem.
…while the U.S. economy has since improved, participation in such programs has generally not declined. This paper concludes that there is ample scope for states to reform welfare, and it proposes two substantial changes: (1) cap welfare spending at the rate of inflation and the number of Americans in poverty; and (2) allow states to direct savings from welfare programs to other budget functions. …this paper finds that federal savings through 2013 would, after accounting for inflation and the number of Americans in poverty, total $1.3 trillion had welfare funding remained at 1998 levels.
The key is federalism.
States should have the freedom to experiment to see what policies are most effective. Under such conditions, successful states would serve as models for other states—and, possibly, models for further federal welfare reform. Indeed, successful welfare reforms have already been observed in North Carolina, New York, Indiana, and Rhode Island. …Providing states increased flexibility to adjust resource levels between welfare programs offers numerous advantages. For instance, states with low food prices but high housing costs might shift resources from SNAP to housing programs. In addition, states could divert funding from existing programs to new ones, such as community-based programs that prove successful.
Her bottom line is that the status quo is a failure.
Antipoverty programs should be judged by how successfully they help lift people out of poverty. By this measure, the country’s welfare programs performed poorly during the Great Recession and its aftermath: welfare costs and eligibility have, as this paper has documented, largely expanded, with few gains in poverty reduction. …The status quo is plainly unacceptable. New solutions, not more funding, are the answer. …empower states to choose welfare policies that best serve their most vulnerable families, as well as those that best fit their political demands.
An excellent study and a very sound proposal.
Though I would make one very important modification.
It’s clearly a step in the right direction if the federal government turns all income-redistribution programs into a block grant so that states can decide how to allocate the money and address poverty.
But the long-run goal should be to eliminate any role for Washington, even as a provider of block grants.
In an ideal world, the block grant should be immediately capped and then gradually phased out. Let state and local governments decide how to tax and spend in this arena.
P.S. Some folks on the right want to replace the current welfare state with a government-guaranteed minimum income. But that approach is very inferior to genuine federalism.
P.P.S. The bureaucrats at the OECD (subsidized by our tax dollars) are pushing a new definition of poverty that is really a stalking horse for more income redistribution.
P.P.P.S. In the spirit of political correctness, here’s the modern version of the Little Red Hen and the modern version of the fable about the ant and the grasshopper.
P.P.P.P.S. For American readers, click here to see the extent to which your state makes welfare more attractive than work.
[…] Instead of moving in the wrong direction, existing redistribution programs need to be scaled back. But that’s just part of the solution. The federal government should get out of the way. […]
[…] be phased out as part of a comprehensive federalism agenda (including big tax cuts). Then states can choose how much to tax and how much to spend. Just like the Founding Fathers […]
[…] obvious takeaway, as I pointed out back in 2015, is that we should we should be expanding on Bill Clinton’s success by replacing other federal […]
[…] obvious takeaway, as I pointed out back in 2015, is that we should we should be expanding on Bill Clinton’s success by replacing other […]
[…] declined in the United States and we are getting worse results. But perhaps a restoration campaign would be politically successful. After all, welfare reform was popular in the 1990s. […]
[…] declined in the United States and we are getting worse results. But perhaps a restoration campaign would be politically successful. After all, welfare reform was popular in the 1990s. […]
[…] federalism has declined in the United States and we are getting worse results. But perhaps a restoration campaign would be politically successful. After all, welfare reform was popular in the 1990s. Why not expand […]
[…] part, my opposition to per-child handouts is motivated by a desire to protect the welfare reform law enacted in the […]
[…] part, my opposition to per-child handouts is motivated by a desire to protect the welfare reform law enacted in the […]
[…] research from the Brookings Institution makes a persuasive case that welfare reform deserves credit for some of the post-1996 […]
[…] research from the Brookings Institution makes a persuasive case that welfare reform deserves credit for some of the post-1996 […]
[…] schemes will subsidize dependency and encourage out-of-wedlock births – thus undermining the very successful welfare reform of the […]
[…] schemes will subsidize dependency and encourage out-of-wedlock births – thus undermining the very successful welfare reform of the […]
[…] welfare reform legislation under Bill Clinton is an example of how to move in the right direction. A top-down program from Washington was turned into a block […]
[…] that system has been bad news for both taxpayers and poor people, a swap sounds very […]
[…] this video shows how the Medicaid program should be “block-granted” (just as welfare was reformed in the […]
[…] create a sense of entitlement and disincentivize hard work, leading to social breakdown in the welfare-addicted underclass communities they create. Meanwhile, many of these same communities (and many others) are […]
[…] is the gold standard for reforming redistribution programs. This was the approach used in the very successful Clinton-era welfare reform, and it should be replicated for other means-tested […]
[…] on Capitol Hill are feeding my accurate information, we may see a bigger and better version of the 1996 welfare reform in 2018. The core concept would be to abolish the dozens of means-tested programs (i.e., […]
[…] And he also opposed Washington-based income redistribution (another sensible view). […]
[…] And he also opposed Washington-based income redistribution (another sensible view). […]
[…] the government can provide enough handouts to induce motherhood (heck, one of the motives for the welfare reform that was adopted during Bill Clinton’s presidency was a concern that the old system was encouraging women to have children out of […]
[…] this video shows how the Medicaid program should be “block-granted” (just as welfare was reformed in the […]
[…] programs for the ostensible purpose of alleviating poverty (e.g.., Medicaid, food stamps, welfare, […]
[…] programs for the ostensible purpose of alleviating poverty (e.g.., Medicaid, food stamps, welfare, […]
[…] For what it’s worth, I’m particularly hopeful (or not un-hopeful, to be more accurate) that Trump will be willing to address Medicaid reform, ideally as part of an overall proposal to block-grant all means-tested programs. […]
[…] from the tremendous success of welfare reform during the Clinton Administration, the entire Washington-based welfare state should be […]
[…] from the tremendous success of welfare reform during the Clinton Administration, the entire Washington-based welfare state should be […]
[…] from the tremendous success of welfare reform during the Clinton Administration, the entire Washington-based welfare state should be […]
[…] from the tremendous success of welfare reform during the Clinton Administration, the entire Washington-based welfare state should be […]
[…] For what it’s worth, I’m particularly hopeful (or not un-hopeful, to be more accurate) that Trump will be willing to address Medicaid reform, ideally as part of an overall proposal to block-grant all means-tested programs. […]
[…] For what it’s worth, I’m particularly hopeful (or not un-hopeful, to be more accurate) that Trump will be willing to address Medicaid reform, ideally as part of an overall proposal to block-grant all means-tested programs. […]
[…] this video shows how the Medicaid program should be “block-granted” (just as welfare was reformed in the […]
[…] effect, the goal should be to replicate the success of the Clinton-era welfare reform, but extending the principle to all redistribution programs (Medicaid, food stamps, EITC, […]
[…] effect, the goal should be to replicate the success of the Clinton-era welfare reform, but extending the principle to all redistribution programs (Medicaid, food stamps, EITC, […]
[…] effect, the goal should be to replicate the success of the Clinton-era welfare reform, but extending the principle to all redistribution programs (Medicaid, food stamps, EITC, […]
[…] from the Austrian School that decentralization is the right approach. We already did that for basic welfare payments during the Clinton years, and we should do it for all other forms of income redistribution, perhaps starting with food […]
[…] shown by the 1996 welfare reform, you’re likely to get changes that are good for both taxpayers and poor […]
[…] shown by the 1996 welfare reform, you’re likely to get changes that are good for both taxpayers and poor […]
[…] What does matter is that we have a malignant welfare state that is eroding the social capital of the country. The entire apparatus should be dismantled and turned over to the states. […]
[…] And one final point to make is that we should do everything possible to shrink the size of the central government in Washington and transfer activities to the private sector or states. This isn’t because states don’t make mistakes, but rather because competition between states will produce far better results than a one-size-fits-all approach from Washington. […]
[…] to this mess. Just get the federal government out of the business of redistributing income. We already got very good results by reforming one welfare program in the 1990s. So let’s build on that […]
[…] 1996 welfare reform was only possible because of several years of work by think tank experts at places like the […]
[…] since great minds think alike, you won’t be surprised to see that Chris and Veronique also want to get the federal […]
[…] view, of course, is that the federal government shouldn’t be in the business of redistributing income, but that’s an issue we discussed a few days […]
[…] federalism model already has been successfully tested with welfare reform in the 1990s and it also is the core feature of proposals to block grant […]
[…] federalism model already has been successfully tested with welfare reform in the 1990s and it also is the core feature of proposals to block grant […]
[…] when advocating more welfare spending in the United States. But we’d be much better off if we learned from the success of welfare reform in the 1990s and got the federal government out of the business of income […]
[…] when advocating more welfare spending in the United States. But we’d be much better off if we learned from the success of welfare reform in the 1990s and got the federal government out of the business of income […]
[…] had successful welfare reform in the 1990s, to be sure, but it dealt with just one […]
[…] that is spent on all redistribution programs, lump those funds into a block grant, and then turn the money over to the states and give them free rein to decide how best to alleviate poverty without creating […]
[…] Building on Success of Clinton-Era Reforms, Let’s Eliminate all DC-Based Income Redistribution […]
dickrichardsky:
My point exactly. The effective tax rate for that individual is 75%.
Let’s assume the flat tax rate is 25%. The federal tax code should be designed so no one pays an effective federal tax rate over 25%. If every adult citizen were to receive $10,000 annually (approximately 100% of the poverty level), with a flat tax of 25%, they would keep 75% of every dollar earned.
Obviously, we have no control over what the states do, but we should make sure that federal programs [whatever you call them] as a whole do not have effective tax rates that exceed the maximum marginal tax rate.
The effective tax rate would progress from negative to approaching 25%, depending on the level of income. [$40,000 would have a 0% effective tax rate.]
If you think 100% of the poverty level is too high for a cash payment, you could lower it, but the trade-off is more disincentive in the welfare/tax system. You also run a bigger risk that a flat tax will never pass and we’ll be stuck with what we have now or worse.
States would have to reconsider their approaches, since dis-incentives using the current welfare approach would go dramatically up.
Mr. Nedland,
I’m not sure I agree with your assertion that this is a taxing issue. Imagine a person getting $15,000 a year in welfare benefits, which would be cut back significantly if he earned, say, $20,000. Let’s say his welfare benefits go down to zero. So, if he took that job, he would have a total income of $20,000, whereas if he stayed on welfare, he would keep the $15,000. That means he would, in essence, be earning $5,000 a year for 2000 working hours in a year – which nets him $2.50 per hour for working. That doesn’t even include the cost of getting to and from work, possible daycare issues, etc., etc., etc. All of this adds up to a huge disincentive to work, regardless of the tax rates.
Those numbers are probably nowhere near accurate, but that should give you a sense of the nature of the issue.
Mr. Dan, this is not directly related to your post, but has anyone developed a macroeconomic metric which I would call the PGDP (Productive GDP)? This would exclude government and luxury//leisure/entertainment spending. The idea is to zero in on the economic things that make us more productive and therefore contribute to our productivity and our wealth. The chunk of our economy spent on college and pro football games, for instance, is only available to be spent because it is the proceeds of our productive endeavors.
It would be interesting to see such a metric graphed over time and in relation to the GDP.
Obviously a lot more thought would have to be given to what is productive and what isn’t. For example, perhaps government road construction spending should count as Productive.
Reblogged this on Brian By Experience.
[…] In an ideal world, the block grant WAIT, THERE’S MORE… […]
My difficulty with this article is that the biggest problem with our current welfare approach is the dis-incentive towards earning income, which is more of a tax problem than a welfare problem.
To alleviate the dis-incentive problem, you must fix the tax system.
Obviously, some form of flat tax is the way to go, HOWEVER, a flat tax that does not give some sort of break to those with lower incomes will not fly politically.
Effective tax rates can be made progressive though either a standard deduction or a cash payment. Separating the tax system from the real world US, a standard deduction might make more sense. BUT, since we need to be socially aware, a cash payment as part of the tax code is a way to solve our dis-incentive dilemma.
The logical amount for the cash payment would be 100% of the poverty line, far less than current combined state/federal amount exceeding 200%. This base amount could not be lost by earning income.
Anything over that amount could be provided by the States as welfare.
Federal block cash to the States is just grafting the broken federal system onto the State systems. And, how would you divide up the block cash? Obviously, based on political “gifts” from the party in power — what a great idea!!
Building the cash payment into the tax code eliminates all of the federal welfare agencies. It eliminates disincentives at least on the federal level. It addresses concerns about the income gap and “living wage” levels. And, it promotes a dynamic workforce, that must have some support for down periods as companies go out of business and new firms open. It is key to a 21st century tax code.
More deadly than income redistribution via DC is the redistribution to rural areas and less prosperous areas. How can federalism work if so many of the legislators and mayors have day jobs working for federally-financed local development authorities or law firms seeking to enhance their bond practices in hyping infrastructure as the lure for future economic development?
We also have all 50 states required this year to submit their state plans under the little covered Workforce Innovation and Opportunity Act–WIOA. http://www.invisibleserfscollar.com/priority-economic-citizenship-for-some-officially-sanctioned-status-as-prey-for-most-of-us/ WIOA is built on the Clinton era Workforce Investment Act, which is the best he could do after School to Work became so controversial. Now School to Work is back but hiding in federal Competency programs being pushed by Labor and the National Governors Association and WIOA.
Plus the UN and the OECD are perfectly aware that their global CIFAL Network is training “local authorities/actors” to pursue their internationalist redistribution agenda using their local powers to control education, collect property taxes, and control land use.
It’s a mistake to just put the focus on income redistribution. Why with Lamar Alexander’s proposed rewrite of the NCLB mental capacities themselves appear to be something DC wants to constrain. In the name of Equity and Equal Opportunity for All of course, Bright, successful, involved parents must no longer provide a boost in educational outcomes.
[…] By Dan Mitchell […]